Hostname: page-component-cb9f654ff-65tv2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-08-29T12:31:40.785Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The ‘internal financing mechanism’ and (hyper)inflation in the wartime Japanese Empire

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 July 2025

Tsz Ho Wong*
Affiliation:
The University of Edinburgh
*
Tsz Ho Wong, Asian Studies, School of Literatures, Languages and Cultures, The University of Edinburgh, Edinburgh, UK, email: t.h.wong-2@sms.ed.ac.uk
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

To sustain a protracted war after losing foreign loans and reserves and being sanctioned by the Allies, Japan used its ‘internal financing mechanism’ to gobble up civilian capital through government bonds, unbacked paper currency and interest rate interventions. These tactics aggrandised the size of the monetary base and money supply in Japan’s home islands and colonies, but also created inflationary pressures. To minimise the risk of (hyper)inflation, the government encouraged civilians to save in order to enrich the capital of financial intermediaries who would then absorb the ever-increasing government bonds. The ideal failed as monetary expansion outstripped economic productivity, even though expansionary monetary policy had to be tolerable in order to supply sufficient credit for war production. Imperial Japan’s use of unsecured credit to finance the war, together with its loose exchange controls, led to the diversion of colonial hyperinflationary pressures to the home islands, multiplying the risk of implosion of the ‘internal financing mechanism’. Although draconian currency controls were subsequently introduced, they further disrupted the empire’s economic order, and eventually led to the collapse of the yen bloc.

Information

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the European Association for Banking and Financial History e.V.

I

While the broader field of modern Japanese history focuses on topics such as military atrocities, settler colonialism, and the mobilisation of resources and science and technology, wartime officials believed that the effectiveness of war finance was a paramount concern in maintaining and sustaining the empire’s order. A statement made by Fukai Eigo (Reference FUKAI1953, p. 415), a privy councillor (sūmitsu komonkan) and former governor of the Bank of Japan (BoJ), to Prime Minister General Koiso Kuniaki during the Privy Council meeting in February 1945 emphasised that inflation could not be solved without considering fiscal policies, such as the issuance of government bonds, the BoJ’s huge loans for production, and the exchange of currencies between Japan’s home islands and its colonies and collaborationist regimes. Fukai’s interpretation of the monetary causes of inflation illustrates that the failure of Japan’s war economy was an issue generated both at home and in the colonies, albeit initially in different ways.

This article uses ‘(hyper)inflation’ instead of ‘hyperinflation’ in the title because the rate of inflation varied across the Japanese Empire.Footnote 1 Hyperinflation in occupied China and Southeast Asia was driven by the issuance of several types of unbacked ‘military scrip-like currencies’ (gunpyō ruiji no tsūka) ‘borrowed’ by the Japanese government to support its colonial military expenditure (Ōkurashō Shōwa zaiseishi henshūshitsu 1955, pp. 167–88, 34–9 [in appendix]; Hara Reference HARA2013, pp. 117–26). Although Japan’s economy was closely linked to these regions, especially China, the hyperinflationary pressures in the colonies do not seem to have been transmitted, or at least not fully, to Japan’s home islands. This article argues that this phenomenon was due to the policy of financing military expenditures with colonial currencies not being implemented until April 1943 (Ono Reference ONO2022 [2021], p. 226), and the influx of colonial currencies into Japan’s home islands did not take place until 1944, a year and a half before the armistice. This was not just a side effect of Japan’s colonial economy during World War II; together with ballooning budget deficits and the increasing amount of government bonds, paper currency and bank loans in Japan’s home islands, it significantly heightened the risk of the empire’s war-financing mechanism imploding. Another factor that prevented the full exposure of colonial hyperinflationary pressures in the home islands was the Japanese government’s subsequent tightening of currency controls, and the third section will show that this in fact further disrupted the empire’s economic order and led to the break-up of the yen bloc.

Current literature has thoroughly demonstrated that Japan’s imperial expansion and its relations with other world powers were intertwined with money and finance (Inoue and Usami Reference INOUE and USAMI1951; Crowley Reference CROWLEY1966; Andō Reference ANDŌ and Andō1979, pp. 3–49; Barnhart Reference BARNHART1987; Myers Reference MYERS, Duus, Myers and Peattie1996, pp. 136–70; Nakamura Reference NAKAMURA, Duus, Myers and Peattie1996; Lee Reference LEE2004, pp. 57–116; Metzler Reference METZLER2006; Ishii Reference ISHII2012; Schiltz Reference SCHILTZ2012; Tanno Reference TANNO2017; Yanagisawa Reference YANAGISAWA and Asai2018, pp. 169–90; Takeda Reference TAKEDA2024). Other earlier works have examined Japan’s war financing tactics during World War II, for instance debt financing, money printing, savings programmes and the exploitative colonial economy (Cohen Reference COHEN1949, pp. 85–97; Itō Reference ITŌ and Oishi1994, pp. 115–52; Hara Reference HARA and Harrison2000 [Reference HARA and Harrison1998], pp. 256–63; Shibata Reference SHIBATA2011; Yamamoto Reference YAMAMOTO2011; Garon Reference GARON2012, pp. 221–54; Huff and Majima Reference HUFF and MAJIMA2013, pp. 937–77; (Huff Reference HUFF, Geyer and Tooze2017 [2015]), pp. 56–93; Huff Reference HUFF2022 [Reference HUFF2020]; Ono Reference ONO2022 [Reference ONO2021]; Sekino Reference SEKINO2021). Previous research, however, has not examined why the government continued to use debt financing throughout the war, even though it was well aware of the risk of money-printing inflation. This article argues that the government was forced to tolerate it because of a lack of capital and production needs. At the turn of the 1940s, the embargo of Japan from the global capital market marked a turning point in Japan’s war financing as the precursors of its colonial expansion were soon affected. For example, in early 1941, Ayukawa Gisuke, head of the Nissan zaibatsu, implemented his plan to withdraw from Manchukuo after failing to secure American and other foreign capital. Ayukawa and the Manchukuo government originally planned that at least one-third of the capital for the development of heavy industry would come from foreign investors (Udagawa Reference UDAGAWA and Tolliday2001, pp. 594–611). The Japanese Empire’s financial difficulties were compounded by wartime disruptions to production, labour and material shortages, and a dysfunctional planned economy (Cohen Reference COHEN1949, pp. 110–92; Ugaki Reference UGAKI1971, vol. 3, p. 1531; Matsumoto Reference MATSUMOTO1988, pp. 126–67). To deal with the ballooning budget deficits, the Japanese government demanded that the (central) banks at home and in the colonies supply unsecured credit (such as loans, unbacked fiat money, and government bonds) to fill its immense capital gap, and thus money-printing inflation was to be expected.Footnote 2 Drawing on parliamentary records and recent research, the second section of this article will explain why the Japanese government believed that a certain degree of inflation and the continued creation of unsecured credit were inevitable to supply sufficient funds for war production and its imperial ambitionsFootnote 3 – an aspect that has not been discussed in previous works.

Japan’s colonial economy in occupied China and Southeast Asia has often been characterised as haphazard, mismanaged, dysfunctional, and a violent exploitation and depredation of capital and resources (Saitō Reference SAITŌ1949, p. 394; Nakamura 1983; Kaneko Reference KANEKO and Oishi1994, pp. 399–440; Hikita Reference HIKITA1995; Yamamoto Reference YAMAMOTO2011, pp. 89–138; Hirai Reference HIRAI2017, pp. 29–47; Seow Reference SEOW2021, pp. 161–207).Footnote 4 The latter was evident in Japan’s money creation schemes in its colonies (Kobayashi Reference KOBAYASHI1993, pp. 153–67; Tatai Reference TATAI2020 [Reference TATAI2002], pp. 185–228; Metzler Reference METZLER2006, p. 264; Kobayashi Reference KOBAYASHI2012, pp. 77–107; Schiltz Reference SCHILTZ2012, p. 217; Cheng Reference CHENG and Cheng2024, pp. 180–93).Footnote 5 However, apart from the unsustainability of the extractive economy (Acemoglu and Robinson Reference ACEMOGLU and ROBINSON2012), a less explored aspect is how the domestic economy was affected, damaged, and gradually encroached upon by the exploitative colonial economy. For example, running the vast British Empire in the nineteenth century proved costly and futile for the British Treasury and taxpayers. Colonial development and investment also diverted capital from the domestic economy, making British industry increasingly uncompetitive and, consequently, less profitable (Davis and Huttenback Reference DAVIS and HUTTENBACK1986). Building on previous literature about Japan’s money creation schemes in its colonies, this article explores the impact of creating unbacked colonial currencies on the economy of Japan’s home islands, which is not yet available in English (and to some extent in Japanese literature, which tends to focus on the impact on the colonies). In fact, a colossal amount of unsecured credit – mainly in the form of BoJ banknotes and bank loans to munitions companies – was being created in the home islands at the same time. Drawing on Fukai’s observations about the impact of expansionary fiscal and monetary policies on Japan’s war economy, this article argues that even if there had been an adequate supply of raw materials and daily necessities in the mid 1940s, the ‘internal financing mechanism’ was at high risk of implosion because of the Japanese war economy’s reliance on unsecured credit that outpaced the empire’s production capacity; and also because of loose and incomplete exchange controls that allowed unbacked colonial currencies to flood into Japan and divert hyperinflationary pressures back home. As for the root cause of Japan’s economic catastrophe in the mid 1940s, it was widely believed that scarcity and starvation, partly caused by the loss of sea power and the Allied strategic bombing campaigns, had brought the empire to its knees. This view was shared by the Japanese in the 1940s, by contemporary Japanese social historians, and even by senior officers of the Kriegsmarine and the ‘Johnston Committee’, an American commission of inquiry into Japanese and Korean economic conditions in 1948, headed by Percy H. Johnston, chairman of the Chemical Bank and Trust Company.Footnote 6 Without intending to diminish the impact or importance of shortages in Japan’s war economy and, more generally, the severity of historical inflation outside Japan, this article expands our understanding of the monetary causes of (hyper)inflation, the inter-empire transmission of (hyper)inflationary pressures and the Japanese Empire’s downfall through the mass issuance of unbacked credit and disastrous currency controls.

This article is divided into two pieces of analysis. The first details the ‘internal financing mechanism’, in the words of Adam Tooze and Jamie Martin (Reference TOOZE, MARTIN, Geyer and Tooze2017 [2015] p. 45), which is an ‘organisational expression of the macroeconomic approach’ adopted by the Japanese government to finance the war. Through analysing the mechanism, this section explains why the Japanese government considered a certain degree of inflation and the endless creation of unsecured credit at home to be tolerable. It also demonstrates the unsustainability of the ‘internal financing mechanism’ under the immense issuance of unsecured credit. The growth of unsecured credit and taxes surpassed that of the nation’s production capacity (nominal GNP) and national income, the latter resulting in a financial burden on civilians. Despite the unsustainability of the mechanism, the absence of robust currency controls accelerated its collapse. The second piece of analysis will address this by examining how meeting military expenditures with ‘borrowed money’ (kari’irekin) significantly multiplied the risk of implosion of the mechanism, and eventually, the collapse of the yen bloc as well as the Japanese Empire’s economic order.

II

Debt financing was the main way in which the Japanese government raised funds to pay for its astronomical war expenditures. This tactic was first used by Takahashi Korekiyo in the early 1930s to recover Japan’s economy from the Great Depression, and then more radically (as this section will show) after the outbreak of the Second Sino-Japanese War in July 1937 to finance the ever-increasing military expenditure until August 1945, and even in the late 1940s to finance the costs of demobilisation and reconstruction (Nolte Reference NOLTE1987, pp. 291–305; Nakamura Reference NAKAMURA1999 [Reference NAKAMURA1994], pp. 53–77; Hara Reference HARA and Harrison2000 [Reference HARA and Harrison1998], pp. 256–63; Metzler Reference METZLER2006, pp. 240–56; Smethurst Reference SMETHURST2007, pp. 268–98). Japan’s debt financing consisted of three pillars: the issuance and absorption of government bonds, taxation, and interest rate intervention. These financing mechanisms facilitated the systematic seizure of civilian wealth, which was then converted into war funds, while a series of institutional reforms and legal restrictions were adopted to ensure their smooth implementation (Okazaki and Okuno-Fujiwara (Reference OKAZAKI, OKUNO-FUJIWARA, Okazaki and Okuno-Fujiwara2002 [1999], pp. 25–30).

First I will clarify the role of money printing, the suppression of private consumption and also the distribution of credit, in other words, the creation and allocation of bank loans, in Japan’s debt financing policy. Printing money and issuing government bonds are two sides of the same coin. The need to underwrite government bonds partly explains the growth of the monetary base and money supply in Japan’s homeland (Aoki Reference AOKI1943, pp. 26–9; Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, p. 208). In the early 1940s, the Japanese government, seeking to shift inflationary pressures to its colonies, decided to finance colonial military expenditures with ‘borrowed money’, the unbacked military scrip (gunpyō), and military scrip-like currencies issued in its wartime colonies and collaborationist regimes, which dramatically aggrandised the monetary base and money supply in the colonies, particularly in the Wang Jingwei regime and in Southeast Asia (Ono Reference ONO2022 [Reference ONO2021], pp. 212, 216).Footnote 7 Since 79 per cent of the newly issued government bonds were to finance military expenditure (Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, p. 169), the financing of military expenditure by colonial currencies can therefore be interpreted as minimising the financial burden on the main bond underwriter – the BoJ – and the risk of money-printing inflation, since the Bank often has to print money to fill the capital gap in underwriting bonds. The suppression of private consumption and the distribution of credit are indispensable for war mobilisation, as they enable the state to secure essential materials and funds for war production; the Japanese government achieved this in part through taxation and savings programmes. The distribution of credit is fundamental to understanding why the government tolerated the consequences of its expansionary fiscal policy and continued with it for a decade.

I call Japan’s debt financing tactic the ‘internal financing mechanism’, which is an ‘organisational expression of the macroeconomic approach’ adopted by the Japanese government to finance the war, but the Japanese government did not coin this term, nor did it use it during or after the war. Jerome B. Cohen (Reference COHEN1949, p. 85), a Japanese language officer in the US Navy who was assigned to the United States Strategic Bombing Survey and studied the files of the Japanese Ministry of Munitions in the late 1940s, used the term ‘internal financing circuit’ to describe the processes of issuance and absorption of government bonds by financial institutions in his 1949 book on Japan’s war economy. Gregg Huff (Reference HUFF, Geyer and Tooze2017 [2015], p. 63), who often cited Cohen’s book in his work, used ‘internal financing mechanism’ to summarise Japan’s approach to war financing. The phrase runs the risk of presenting an ex-post view, oversimplifying various fractional temporary financing policies and putting them under one umbrella term. Japanese policymakers may not have had a grand and unifying scheme such as the ‘internal financing mechanism’, but their directions for war financing nevertheless showed consistency. According to some shared principles in the issuance of credit and the BoJ’s monetary policy, the officials aimed to strengthen, or at least maintain, Japan’s war capability while stabilising the economic and financial order. They understood that inflation was inevitable due to the ever-increasing expenditures and the amount of government bonds, as well as increased demand for labour and raw materials, and thus their focus was on keeping inflation at a manageable level, as evidenced by parliamentary records. At a meeting of the House of Representatives in March 1939, Ishiwata Sōtarō, the Minister of Finance, stated: ‘it seems that you [Ōmoto Sadatarō] acknowledge that a certain degree of price increase is inevitable given the large-scale issuance of government bonds. To some extent, I agree with that view.’ Yet, Ishiwata believed that there was no severe inflation or hyperinflation at present.Footnote 8 At another meeting of the House of Representatives in January 1941, Kawada Isao, then Minister of Finance, in response to Sugiura Takeo’s question about the prices of raw materials and daily necessities, said: ‘it is clear that inflation is acceptable, but hyperinflation is problematic.’Footnote 9 In the later stages of the war, another Minister of Finance, Kaya Okinori, told the House of Representatives in January 1943 that ‘the most dangerous threat to economic order during wartime is the phenomenon of hyperinflation …We are working to suppress this threat through comprehensive measures, including the policies of taxation, savings, material control, and production increase’.Footnote 10 In January 1945, Ishiwata Sōtarō, who had been reappointed as Minister of Finance, acknowledged in the House of Peers that in a wartime economy, monetary expansion was ‘inevitable’, and also the ‘inflationary situation will inevitably arise to some extent.’ Ishiwata believed that the inflation problem was also rooted in wages and the supply of goods, but ‘to maintain economic order on the home front, it is essential to control it.’Footnote 11

Ministerial speeches in the Diet also give some indication of how Japanese wartime officials thought about the causes of hyperinflation or runaway inflation. They believed that it resulted from an imbalance between the supply of goods and money, and the circulation of excess capital. In March 1940, Sakurauchi Yukio, the Minister of Finance, told the House of Representatives that hyperinflation was ‘a situation in which the currency over-expands, leading to a loss of confidence in it, causing prices to rise uncontrollably, thereby destabilising the economy’.Footnote 12 In February 1941, Kawada Isao stated in the House of Representatives: ‘in the present situation, if materials are available and if the balance between materials and money can be maintained, I believe that hyperinflation will not occur. The real problem, I think, lies in the possible imbalance between resources and demand.’Footnote 13 The Japanese government therefore employed mechanisms of issuing and absorbing government bonds, tax collection, and keeping interest rates low to provide sufficient funds for war production and to prevent runaway inflation under an expansionary fiscal policy. These mechanisms were identical to the ‘comprehensive measures’ involving savings, taxation, production and material control that Kaya Okinori mentioned in his 1943 speech to the Diet.Footnote 14 Thus, by using the term ‘internal financing mechanism’, this article does not mean to imply that Japanese officials had such a comprehensive scheme in mind at the beginning of World War II. Rather, it shows that various temporary financing policies, albeit fractional and fragmentary, followed the guiding principle of mobilising the nation’s financial resources for the planned economic system and the war.

In addition, the idea of absorbing government bonds through bank deposits and postal savings, whether successful or not, demonstrated an intention to recycle surplus capital in the market to pay for the bonds. This intention was expressed in Ishiwata Sōtarō’s speech in the House of Representatives in February 1939, when he said: ‘there is the distribution of government funds, and as these funds are distributed, they are returned as savings. These savings are then used to cover the redemption of government bonds.’Footnote 15 Recycling of funds was another feature of Japan’s wartime circuit-like financing tactics, especially when the government lost its foreign reserves and was sanctioned by the Allies. As a side note, the term ‘internal financing mechanism’ has been used to describe the mechanism by which the zaibatsu families financed their businesses with their own capital (Teranishi Reference TERANISHI, Okazaki and Okuno-Fujiwara2002 [Reference TERANISHI, Okazaki and Okuno-Fujiwara1999], p. 69). Thus, the use of ‘internal financing mechanism’ in this article was an extension of its earlier use to characterise the tendency towards a self-sufficient, if not autarkic, war economy.

The Japanese government’s debt financing consisted of three pillars: the issuance and absorption of government bonds, taxation, and interest rate intervention. While detailing these components, this article will highlight the unsustainability of the system, namely: the scale of debt financing and tax increases exceeded the nation’s nominal GNP and the increase in national income respectively. Given that the maturity of the bonds issued during World War II was often more than a decade,Footnote 16 it is remarkable that Japan’s debt financing has become a financial burden not only for the current generation but also for their descendants (Ōuchi Reference ŌUCHI1949 [Reference ŌUCHI1947], pp. 60–1).

Even before the outbreak of war with China in 1937, Takahashi Korekiyo had experimented with debt financing during his tenure as finance minister. Table 3 shows the scale of debt financing in terms of nominal GNP, government expenditure, the amount of government bonds and the nation’s total liability. Total liability refers to the outstanding amount of government bonds, treasury bills, various government certificates and the ‘borrowed money’. During the war, government bonds remained the primary component of the nation’s liability, with more than 90 per cent of the liability stemming from the outstanding amount of government bonds by 1943. In 1944, however, an exception occurred, as the proportion of ‘borrowings’ increased to 26 per cent, most likely attributable to the substantial amount of ‘borrowed money’ from the colonies. By 1937, the government bonds-nominal GNP ratio had moderately increased, remaining at around 50 to 60 per cent. From 1937 to the outbreak of the Pacific War, the bonds-nominal GNP ratio began to increase at a more substantial scale compared to the previous six years, reaching 90 per cent of the nominal GNP in 1941. The onset of the Pacific War, as evidenced in Table 3, marked a point at which the amount of bonds surpassed the nominal GNP. In 1944, the amount of bonds reached 1.4 times the nominal GNP, and when including the ‘borrowed money’, treasury bills and government certificates, the nation’s total liability in 1944 was two times its nominal GNP. This indicates that during the Pacific War, the Japanese government possessed a liability that was greater than its production capacity.

An increase in government bonds and other forms of liability could be explained by the rise in military expenses. During his tenure as finance minister, as noted by Hara Akira (Reference HARA and Harrison2000 [Reference HARA and Harrison1998], p. 256) and Richard Smethurst (Reference SMETHURST2007, p. 274), Takahashi Korekiyo made efforts to control military expenditure. As shown in Table 3, from 1931 to 1936, military expenditure remained at less than 15 per cent of the total expenditure, while the military expenditure-nominal GNP ratio was between 4 to 6 per cent. When the war with China began, military expenditure steadily increased, equaling almost half the total expenditure in 1944. A similar trend is evident in the military expenditure-nominal GNP ratio, which reached 46.7 per cent of the nominal GNP in 1944. Moreover, as Table 3 shows, after the establishment of the special account for Emergency Armaments Expenditure (rinji gunjihi, EAE) in September 1937, the government began to divert most of its military expenses into this account. By 1945, 62 per cent of the EAE was covered by government bonds, a significant portion of which were underwritten by the BoJ and the Deposit Bureau of the Ministry of Finance. This observation would explain the relationship between government bonds and the nation’s monetary expansion.

From 1937 to 1941, the BoJ and the Deposit Bureau underwrote an average of 68.7 per cent and 22.2 per cent of government bonds, respectively. From 1941 to 1944, the BoJ continued to underwrite 67.9 per cent of newly issued government bonds, while the amount underwritten by the Deposit Bureau increased to 31.6 per cent (Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, p. 173). Since the BoJ had to print money to underwrite the ever-increasing government, it therefore partly explained the growth of Japan’s monetary base and money supply. From 1937 to 1941, the amount of newly issued BoJ banknotes increased by 2.6 times (Ōkurashō and Nihon ginkō 1948, p. 259), while the monetary base and M1 increased by 2.5 and 2.6 times, respectively (Table 2). In 1944, the BoJ issued 17.7 billion yen worth of banknotes, representing a threefold increase compared to 1941. During this period, the monetary base and M1 increased by 2.5 and 2.1 times, respectively (Table 2), reaching levels comparable to those observed between 1937 and 1941. However, the nominal GNP increased by only 1.9 times between 1937 and 1941, and was further trimmed to 1.7 times between 1941 and 1944 (Table 3). In other words, the magnitude of monetary expansion exceeded the growth of production in the broader economy.

The Japanese government did not leave the expansion of the amount of government bonds, currency in circulation and money supply unchecked. The plan was to enrich the capital of financial institutions through savings campaigns, and then the financial institutions would purchase the government bonds previously underwritten by the BoJ, thereby minimising the inflationary pressure caused by the newly issued debt and absorbing surplus funds from the private markets (Aoki Reference AOKI1943, pp. 26–9). This seemed to have been successful, as the growth in the amount of government bonds was slower than the growth in the deposits at the BoJ, the Deposit Bureau and other financial institutions, including commercial and savings banks, trusts and insurance companies. As stated above, between 1937 and 1941, the government issued 7.55 times the amount of bonds compared to those issued between 1931 and 1936. From 1941 to 1944, the amount of newly issued bonds was 7.7 times greater than those issued between 1937 and 1941. Meanwhile, from 1937 to 1941, the deposits at the BoJ, the Deposit Bureau, and other financial institutions increased by 2.9 times, 2.5 times, and 8.2 times respectively. From 1941 to 1944, their deposits further increased by 5.2 times, 3.1 times and 2.3 times, respectively (Tables 1a and 1b).Footnote 17 However, if we compare the growth of government bonds, the BoJ’s paper currency and the monetary base for either 1937 to 1941 or 1941 to 1944 with the nominal GNP figures for the same period, even though deposits at various financial institutions grew faster than government bonds, the scale of monetary expansion exceeded the growth of economic productivity. As expected by Japanese officials, the uneven growth between production and government bonds, paper currency in circulation, money supply and monetary base led to inflation.Footnote 18 Yet inflation as measured by Tokyo’s wholesale price index was mild, rising by 43.9 per cent between 1937 and 1941 and 66.3 per cent between 1941 and 1945 (Table 1c). The average monthly inflation rate between August 1941 and August 1945 was merely 2 per cent (Table 6). This was an unusually low rate for a wartime state heavily reliant on debt financing, resulting in part from price controls that artificially suppressed raw materials and consumer goods at the turn of the 1940s, and also from strict regulations on consumption (taxation, rationing, and others) that left nothing to buy (Saitō Reference SAITŌ1949, pp. 90–1). The consequences of Japan’s expansionary fiscal policy were more evident in its wartime colonies, where price controls were poorly implemented, but this will be discussed in the third section of this article.

Table 1a. Japan’s monetary base, money supply, interest rate and inflation measures (1931–45.8) (in thousands of yen)

Table 1b. Japan’s monetary base, money supply, interest rate and inflation measures (1931–45.8) (in thousands of yen)

Table 1c. Japan’s monetary base, money supply, interest rate, and inflation measures (1931–45.8) (in thousands of yen)

Tables 1a, 1b and 1c source: Ōkurashō大蔵省 and Nihon ginkō 日本銀行(eds.), Zaisei keizai tōkei nenpō Shōwa 23-nen 財政経済統計年報 昭和23年 (Tokyo: Ōkurazaimu kyōkai, 1948).

Table 2. Money supply in Japan (M1) (1931–45.8) (in thousands of yen)

Source: Ōkurashō and Nihon ginkō (eds.), Zaisei keizai tōkei nenpō Shōwa 23-nen.

Taxation was another pillar of debt financing, used to finance government expenditure, pay interest on government bonds, absorb public funds and encourage people to save. Driven by the enormous pressure for reform, both financial and social, a tax reform was introduced in 1940 (Revelant Reference REVELANT2015, p. 446). Citing Henry Shavell and Jerome Cohen, Gregg Huff (Reference HUFF, Geyer and Tooze2017 [2015], p. 62) stated that Japan ‘made no serious attempt to adapt the tax system to provide a large share of war finance’, and claimed that the 1940 Tax Reform Law did not apply to corporations. William W. Lockwood (Reference LOCKWOOD1974 [1968], p. 526), on the contrary, argued that the 1940 tax reform ‘overhauled’ the entire tax system and made the income tax ‘an effective revenue instrument’. The evidence suggests that Lockwood’s description is more accurate. Soon after the armistice, Saitō Eizaburō (Reference SAITŌ1949, p. 40) noted that the tax burden on a Japanese individual tripled from 1941 to 1945. Recent research has also revealed that the 1940 Tax Reform introduced a new progressive corporate tax (hōjin zei), and ambitious increases in the corporate tax, personal income tax (shotoku zei), and temporary income tax (rinji ritoku zei) were implemented (Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, pp. 50–3, 144–60).

The increase in taxes led to significant growth in tax revenue, while the tax burden on Japanese civilians rose considerably (Tables 3 and 4). Tax revenues, however, remained at around 10 to 15 per cent of total government’s revenue. From 1941 to 1944, the corporate tax, personal income tax and temporary income tax contributed 61 to 69 per cent of the total tax revenue. All of these taxes had been significantly increased during the Pacific War. A new progressive corporate tax was introduced in 1940, ranging from 25 to 65 per cent. The corporate tax was further increased to 35 to 75 per cent in 1942 and to 40 to 80 per cent in 1945. The much more ambitious personal income tax was divided into ‘classified income tax’ and ‘integrated income tax’. The classified income tax ranged from 6 to 10 per cent in 1940 and rose to 16 to 27 per cent in 1945, whilst the integrated income tax ranged from 2 to 58.8 per cent in 1940 and shifted to 1.8 to 68.7 per cent in 1945. As a result, the income tax rate of the most affluent Japanese could be as high as 80 per cent. The temporary income tax was mainly targeted at industrialists and manufacturers who benefited from the wartime expansion of munitions production. The tax was first introduced in 1935, with an individual rate of 8 per cent and a corporate rate of 10 per cent. The individual rate was increased to 30 per cent in 1940 and a progressive rate was introduced for corporate taxpayers, ranging from 25 to 65 per cent. The individual rate was further increased to 35 per cent in 1942, while the progressive corporate rate was increased to 35 to 75 per cent in 1942 and 40 to 80 per cent in 1945 (Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, pp. 144–60).

Table 3. Japan’s nominal GNP, the amount of government bonds, and government’s revenue and expenditure (in thousands of yen) (1931–44)

Source: Ōkurashō and Nihon ginkō (eds.), Zaisei keizai tōkei nenpō Shōwa 23-nen; Ryōichi Sanwa 三和良一 and Akira Hara 原朗, Kingendai Nihon keizaishi yōran (hoteiban) 近現代日本経済史要覧(補訂版) (Tokyo: Tōkyō daigaku shuppankai, 2021 [2010]), 2–3.

Table 4. Japan’s national income, tax revenue and taxes per capita (1931–44) (national income and tax revenue: in thousands of yen; population: in thousands)

Source: Ōkurashō Shōwa zaiseishi henshūshitsu 大蔵省昭和財政史編集室 (ed.), Shōwa zaiseishi dai 5-kan sozei 昭和財政史 第5卷 租税 (Tokyo: Tōyō keizai shinpōsha, 1957).

The increase in taxes placed a financial burden on civilians. From 1931 to 1944, taxes per capita increased eightfold from 23 yen to 188 yen, while national income increased fourfold. In other words, the increase in taxes was twice that of national income. An identical trend can be found during the Pacific War. From 1941 to 1944, the amount of tax per capita increased by three times, while the national income increased by only 1.5 times (Table 4). The uneven growth between the amount of tax per capita and national income showed how the income tax, if not the entire tax system, had become ‘an effective revenue instrument’.

Taxation generated 10.3 billion yen in revenue for the Japanese government by the end of the war. The amount of taxation in 1945 was only about one-fourteenth of the amount of the government bonds, but it was still responsible for numerous expenses, including financing part of the EAE, regular (nenkin) and invalids’ pensions (onkyū) for military personnel, the cost of air defence, conscription, the development of the munitions industry and, most importantly, the payment of interest on government bonds (Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, pp. 35, 50–3), making the tax system an indispensable part of the ‘internal financing mechanism’.

The last pillar was interest rate intervention, which was closely linked to the issuance of government bonds and the creation of credit. Lowering interest rates was one of the core elements of Takahashi Korekiyo’s fiscal policy. Low interest rates allowed the Japanese government to issue government bonds cheaply, as the government needed to issue a considerable amount of bonds to cover the deficits caused by the recovery programme after the Great Depression. Takahashi also understood that, as the Japanese economy began to recover, people would spend more money, demand would increase and businessmen would begin to look for capital to expand production in order to meet that demand. Low interest rates were essential to this process, as it would be easier for businessmen to borrow money for industrial and commercial expansion. In addition, low interest rates drove up the stock market, which made it possible to raise funds for further growth (Nakamura Reference NAKAMURA1999 [Reference NAKAMURA1994], pp. 58–9; Smethurst Reference SMETHURST2007, p. 258). Interest rates remained low throughout the war, in order to maintain industrial production and war capacity. In July 1937, Kaya Okinori, then Minister of Finance, mentioned in his speech to the House of Peers that ‘it is expected that the demand for funds will continue to increase substantially in the future. To meet this demand, it is necessary to ensure the smooth supply of funds and to keep interest rates as low as possible.’Footnote 19 Under the planned economic system, the disparity between deposit and lending rates – the differences between the highest and lowest interest rates on deposits and loans – was trimmed considerably over the period from 1937 to 1945. In the words of the official history of the BoJ, it was ‘as if a world of finance had materialised in which interest rates were irrelevant. In other words, government control of fund allocation and credit rationing had become widespread throughout the economy’ (Ueda Reference UEDA, Okazaki and Okuno-Fujiwara2002 [Reference UEDA, Okazaki and Okuno-Fujiwara1999], pp. 50–1).

Under the Temporary Capital Adjustment Act, introduced in September 1937, government permission was required for the formation of new companies and for capital increases, mergers or changes of business. It required banks to adjust their lending policies to prevent the flow of funds into industries that were not critical to the war. In doing so, all industries were divided into three groups: Class I were munitions producers and directly related industries, which were given unconditional access to funds, while Class III were those industries with relatively low military priority, such as textiles, which were excluded from further new funding. Class II consisted of industries of intermediate military importance, which were treated on a case-by-case basis according to predetermined criteria (Nakamura Reference NAKAMURA1999 [Reference NAKAMURA1994], p. 90; Baxter Reference BAXTER2007, p. 175). State intervention in lending practices shows its aim to control and maximise funds for war production, which was prioritised over all other sectors.

In the first half of the 1940s, the scope for banks to make independent credit decisions continued to narrow. The major and regional private banks began to participate in syndicated loans arranged by the Industrial Bank of Japan. With the introduction of the Law on War Supply Companies in December 1943, a system of selected financial institutions for war supply loans was established. The government designated certain banks to provide funds and services to specific munitions companies. If more funds were needed than could be provided by the lead banks, which were usually major commercial banks, other banks would join the financing groups on the government’s instructions. (Baxter Reference BAXTER2007, pp. 179–80, 187). As a result, the amount of bank loans increased dramatically in the final phase of the war. In March 1945, Mitsubishi Bank lent a total of 7.26 billion yen, and also provided 2.95 billion yen to munitions companies for their own financing, which was 1.82 billion yen more than its deposits. Similarly, the Imperial Bank had lent 14.3 billion yen with only 13.3 billion yen in deposits. They filled the capital gap by borrowing from the BoJ, with Mitsubishi Bank’s 2.15 billion yen and Imperial Bank’s 5.43 billion yen coming from the BoJ. By the end of World War II, the commercial loans of BoJ accounted for 30.4 billion yen, three times more than the amount of government bonds it held. The BoJ financed itself by printing money, and had issued 42.3 billion yen worth of banknotes by August 1945, which inevitably increased inflation, and eventually led to a devaluation of people’s savings. Apart from the depreciation in the real value of Japan’s monetary base and money supply (Table 1c), the devaluation can also be seen in the face value of the new banknotes. In 1944, the BoJ issued a total of 526,880 notes, of which 319,290 were 10 yen notes and 159,290 were 100 yen notes. The amount of 100 yen was 824.9 times more than in 1943. In 1945, however, the BoJ printed 1,621,057 banknotes, including 664,467 of 100 yen, 20,747 of 500 yen and 12,830 of 1,000 yen (Cohen Reference COHEN1949, pp. 88–91; Ōkurashō Shōwa zaiseishi henshūshitsu 1956, p. 172; Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, pp. 205–8). Devalued notes were thus flooding the market, and while the consequences were obvious, the causes appeared mysterious to ordinary people.

Why did the BoJ tolerate the risk of inflation and continue to print money to support their loans to private banks? This is because Japanese industry, especially the war supply companies, became increasingly dependent on indirect financing as the war progressed. In June 1940, financial institutions lent 5.2 billion yen to industrialists (including textile, metal, chemical, mechanical, food, and electrical) and another 748 million yen to the mining sector, an amount equal to 47 per cent of the total loans made by financial institutions. The amount of loans increased significantly during the Pacific War. In June 1944, financial institutions extended a total of 35.6 billion yen in loans, of which 17.7 billion yen went to industrialists (50 per cent) and 1.8 billion yen to the mining sector (5 per cent) (Hara Reference HARA2013, p. 367). Furthermore, the proportion of zaibatsu using external capital to finance their businesses, such as bank loans, corporate bonds, and funds raised on the stock market, continued to grow during the war. In 1937, 39 per cent of the capital of the Mitsui zaibatsu was external capital, rising to 53 per cent in 1941 and 68 per cent in 1945. Similar trends can be observed in the Mitsubishi and Sumitomo zaibatsu (Takeda Reference TAKEDA2020, p. 193). Thus, even if the BoJ recognised the danger of printing money to lend, it would have to accept the risk. Indeed, the Shōwa zaiseishi edited by the Ministry of Finance and the official history of the BoJ show an awareness that this tactic led to inflation (Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, pp. 207–8). If the BoJ stopped lending to private banks, industrialists might not get enough credit for production, which would eventually lead to the collapse of Japan’s economic order and its war machine. At a time of national crisis, it was too big to fail.

III

Building on the previous analysis of the components of wartime Japan’s ‘internal financing mechanism’ and its unsustainability due to the inevitable creation of immense unsecured credit, this section explores the fiscal failure of the wartime Japanese Empire from another perspective – the impact of Japan’s exploitative colonial economy on the home islands.

A common explanation was that inflation in Japan’s home islands was caused by rising prices driven up by shortages of raw materials (see footnote 6). It is true that everyone in the Japanese Empire, regardless of status or wealth, suffered from shortages of necessities (especially food) and black market prices in the final stages of World War II.Footnote 20 This was anticipated by the Japanese government. From July 1937, when Japan was at war with China, goods became scarce and prices naturally rose. In order to curb inflationary pressures, the government, other than encouraging thrift, set official prices as ceilings. Originally, the official price was to apply only to selected major items, but it was later extended to all kinds of goods, and black markets began to flourish. When war broke out in Europe in September 1939, shortages became widespread both domestically and internationally, as there were only two major countries that were not yet involved in the war – the US and the Soviet Union. The Japanese government then promulgated an imperial order, commonly known as the 18 September Price and Wage Freeze Order (Kakaku-tō tōsei rei). According to the order, the government would freeze wages and prices to buy time to draw up comprehensive wage and price schedules. The official price list was drawn up in 1940, setting the official price for 40,000 items in the capital and 430,000 items in the regions. Meanwhile, in the autumn of 1939, there was a drought in western Japan due to a shortage of electricity, and the rice harvest in western Japan and Korea was poor. At the same time, shortages of other necessities such as sugar began to be severely felt. As a result, necessities such as rice, sugar, miso, and soy sauce were rationed, and ration coupons (haikyūken) were issued to the public (Nakamura Reference NAKAMURA1999 [Reference NAKAMURA1994], pp. 98–101). Official prices were of course well below the market prices, so Japan’s inflation, as reflected in the Tokyo wholesale price index, was indeed a ‘suppressed’ inflation. Similar to Germany in the second half of World War I, the maximum price regulations prevented the full impact of expansionary monetary policy from being reflected in price movements, or at least in official price movements (Holtfrerich Reference HOLTFRERICH and Balderston1986, pp. 12–13, 85–6). The impact of shortages on inflation could not be denied, and yet this article argues that there was an overlooked factor that contributed to Japan’s wartime inflation, namely: the influx of unbacked colonial currencies. These colonial currencies brought hyperinflationary pressures from abroad, and eventually disrupted the financial order in Japan’s home islands.

The previous section has shown that in Japan’s home islands, monetary expansion outstripped the growth of industrial production. The monetary base and money supply (M2) grew more rapidly in the colonies than at home (Table 5), as the Japanese government sought to shift the costs of expansionary monetary and fiscal policies to its colonies by financing military expenditure with ‘borrowed money’. Ironically, this attempt eventually led to the diversion of the colonial inflationary pressures to Japan’s home islands. Government bonds and ‘borrowed money’ contributed 61.8 and 24.6 per cent respectively to the EAE. From April 1943 to August 1945, the Japanese government borrowed a total of 42.7 billion yen from its colonies and collaborationist regimes (excluding Taiwan and Korea), but never repaid it. ‘Borrowed money’ refers to the Indochinese piastres, the Thai baht, the Manchukuo yuan, and three types of ‘military scrip-like currencies’ ‘borrowed’ by the Japanese government to support its colonial military expenditure. Military scrip or military scrip-like currencies are the unbacked banknotes used as new colonial currencies and payments for intra-imperial trade and investment. At total of 48.4 per cent of ‘borrowed money’ came from the scrip issued by the Central Reserve Bank (CRB) of the Wang Jingwei regime, 26 per cent from the Southern Development Bank (SDB) in Southeast Asia, 12 per cent from the United Preparatory Bank of China (UPBC), also associated with Wang’s regime. In other words, 60 per cent of the colonial wealth that funnelled into Japan’s war machine was extracted from occupied China (excluding Manchukuo) (Ōkurashō Shōwa zaiseishi henshūshitsu 1955, pp. 167–88, 34–9 [in appendix]; Ono Reference ONO2022 [Reference ONO2021], pp. 212, 226). All the banks were run by collaborationist regimes, except the SDB.

Table 5a. The monetary base and money supply in the Japanese Colonies (1941–5.8) (in thousands of yen)

Table 5b. The monetary base and money supply in the Japanese Colonies (1941–5.8) (in thousands of yen)

Table 5c. The monetary base and money supply in the Japanese colonies (1941–5.8) (in thousands of yen)

Sources: Zhongwai jingji huibao 中外經濟彙報; Ōkurashō and Nihon Ginkō eds., Zaisei keizai tōkei nenpō Shōwa 23-nen; Shin’ichi Gotō 後藤新一, Nihon no kin'yū tōkei 日本の金融統計 (Tokyo: Tōyō keizai shinposha, 1970); Yoshimasa Shibata 柴田善雅, Senryōchi tsūka kin'yū seisaku no tenkai 占領地通貨金融政策の展開 (Tokyo: Nihon keizai hyōronsha, 1999).

BoT: Bank of Taiwan 株式会社台湾銀行

BoC: Bank of Chōsen 朝鮮銀行

CRB: Central Bank of Manchukuo 満洲中央銀行

BoM: Bank of Mengjiang 蒙疆銀行

The SDB shows how a colonial institution gobbled up civilian capital and recycled it to the state and elites. The bank was established in April 1942 to fill the capital void in Southeast Asia after the Allied international banks, such as HSBC and the Mercantile Bank of India, were closed and subsequently liquidated under Japanese military occupation. The bank was set up to finance Japanese industry and long-term resource development in the area, but also to print military scrip (Huff Reference HUFF2022 [Reference HUFF2020], p. 88). The Tokyo government provided 100 million yen as its capital, but only provided 58.4 million yen (from the government bonds) when it was established. Like the financial intermediaries, the SDB had to rely on private and civilian capital, so it could provide billions to the military and Japanese enterprises. From 1943 until the armistice, it lent 11.1 billion yen to the Army and Navy, and 523 million yen to 161 business corporations. The former relied on the 20 billion yen of scrip printed by the SDB, while the latter was covered by bonds and loans from banks, insurance companies and the Deposit Bureau. The Deposit Bureau also bought 20 million yen of the SDB bonds (Takaishi Reference TAKAISHI1960, pp. 386–7, 390). All these tactics depended on the exploitation of civilian capital.

A colossal amount of unbacked scrip led directly to hyperinflation in occupied China and Southeast Asia. When the SDB issued 20 billion yen in unbacked scrip to meet military demands, it caused hyperinflation in Japanese-occupied Southeast Asia; for instance, the cost of living in Manila and Rangoon increased 143 and 1856 times respectively between December 1941 and August 1945 (Ono Reference ONO2022 [Reference ONO2021], p. 212). In order to meet the ever-increasing military expenditure, the CRB and UPBC also continued to print scrip in occupied China. In December 1941, the total amount of scrip issued by the UPBC and CRB was 966 million yen and 280 million yen, and on 10 August 1945 it was 84.9 billion yen and 2.1 trillion yen, an increase of 87.9 and 7,632 times respectively. According to the printed amount, the actual exchange rates between one Japanese yen and per 100 yen UPBC and CRB scrip were 0.41 and 0.1995 in December 1941, and depreciated to 0.0004 and 0.00001 on 10 August 1945. This eventually led to hyperinflation in Shanghai, the financial centre of China (Table 6) (Ōkurashō Shōwa zaiseishi henshūshitsu 1955, p. 304; Ono Reference ONO2022 [Reference ONO2021], p. 229). That is why, in June 1945, Zhou Fohai (Reference ZHOU2003, vol. 2, p. 1023), the mayor of Shanghai, told Tani Masayuki, Tsuchita Yutaka and Ogura Masatsune that ‘Japan cannot create hyperinflation and social unrest in China while it wants to maintain peace between two countries’. The scrip in Shanghai and other Japanese-occupied regions had already become ‘trash papers’ before the Japanese defeat.

Table 6. Monthly wholesale prices and inflation in Tokyo, Beijing and Shanghai (1941.8–1945.8)

Sources: Shiken tōkei geppō 支研統計月報; Senshichū kin'yū tōkei yōran: Shōwa 12-nen kara Shōwa 20-nen (8-gatsu) made 戦時中金融統計要覧 : 昭和12年から昭和20年(8月)迄 (Tokyo: Nihon ginkō tōkeikyoku, 1947).

A mechanism was therefore put in place to prevent hyperinflation from spreading from the colonies to Japan. In August 1942, an agreement was made between the Yokohama Specie Bank (YSB)’s Shanghai branch and the CRB, which offered the Japanese military and government the opportunity to request an ‘unlimited amount’ of military scrip-like currencies. When the Japanese military or government requested CRB’s scrip, the YSB’s Shanghai branch would record yen funds as CRB claims, and accordingly the CRB would provide the Japanese with the equivalent amount of scrip at an exchange rate of 1:18. Initially, the Japanese Treasury in Tokyo would provide cash equivalent to the CRB’s scrip, which the YSB’s Shanghai branch would record as the CRB’s claims. However, this arrangement appeared to be too advantageous to the YSB, and could exacerbate inflation in Japan. It was thus decided to replace the cash with the 3.5 per cent interest bearing government bonds. This meant that the Japanese government would be able to repay the amount after a certain period of time, and that the financing of military expenditure would not depend solely on financial institutions in Japan and the BoJ banknotes. In the following two years, similar arrangements were applied to the EAE relating to the Wang Jingwei regime, Manchukuo, and Southeast Asia. The Japanese government intended to use this mechanism to reduce the risk of inflation at home while creating hyperinflation in its colonies (Ōkurashō Shōwa zaiseishi henshūshitsu 1955, pp. 301–3; Ono Reference ONO2022 [Reference ONO2021], pp. 226–9).Footnote 21

A mechanism was therefore put in place to prevent hyperinflation from spreading from the colonies to Japan. In August 1942, an agreement was made between the Yokohama Specie Bank (YSB)’s Shanghai branch and the CRB, which offered the Japanese military and government the opportunity to request an ‘unlimited amount’ of military scrip-like currencies. When the Japanese military or government requested CRB’s scrip, the YSB’s Shanghai branch would record yen funds as CRB claims, and accordingly the CRB would provide the Japanese with the equivalent amount of scrip at an exchange rate of 1:18. Initially, the Japanese Treasury in Tokyo would provide cash equivalent to the CRB’s scrip, which the YSB’s Shanghai branch would record as the CRB’s claims. However, this arrangement appeared to be too advantageous to the YSB, and could exacerbate inflation in Japan. It was thus decided to replace the cash with the 3.5 per cent interest bearing government bonds. This meant that the Japanese government would be able to repay the amount after a certain period of time, and that the financing of military expenditure would not depend solely on financial institutions in Japan and the BoJ banknotes. In the following two years, similar arrangements were applied to the EAE relating to the Wang Jingwei regime, Manchukuo, and Southeast Asia. The Japanese government intended to use this mechanism to reduce the risk of inflation at home while creating hyperinflation in its colonies (Ōkurashō Shōwa zaiseishi henshūshitsu 1955, pp. 301–3; Ono Reference ONO2022 [Reference ONO2021], pp. 226–9).Footnote 21

The mechanism, however, failed because there was no comprehensive currency control to block the flow of colonial currencies to Japan’s home islands in a timely and effective manner. The lack of currency control can be partly explained by the fact that Japan maintained strong economic and trade links with its colonies and collaborationist regimes until the end of World War II. In May 1944, Igarashi Torao of the Foreign Bureau of the BoJ mentioned that it was ‘practically impossible to completely prohibit the transactions between Japan and its colonies, and of course, it is not feasible to allow unrestricted transactions’.Footnote 22 A similar observation was later made by Fukai Eigo (Reference FUKAI1953, p. 415) at the Privy Council meeting in February 1945.

When did currency exchange between Japan’s home islands and its colonies become an issue? The significant devaluation of colonial currencies began in April 1943 when the policy of financing military expenditures with colonial currencies was implemented in occupied China (excluding Manchukuo, Hong Kong, and Hainan) and Southeast Asia (excluding Thailand and Indochina) (Ono Reference ONO2022 [2021], p. 226). However, the Japanese government maintained a fixed exchange rate (1:1) between the yen and all colonial currencies, except the CRB scrip (1 yen equalled 18 CRB yuan). This policy was assured in practice. The hyperinflated CRB scrip created an accounting problem for Japanese companies with headquarters in Japan and branches or subsidiaries in Shanghai to consolidate their Shanghai balance sheets with the yen-denominated balance sheets of the Japanese headquarters (Katano Reference KATANO1946). While the fixed exchange rate posed difficulties for trade between Japan and its closely linked colonies (Hara Reference HARA2013, pp. 119–24), it also presented an opportunity for Japanese in the occupied regions to subsidise the rising cost of living in Japan (especially black-market prices) or to leverage their profits by exchanging hyperinflated colonial currencies for Japanese yen (Shibata Reference SHIBATA and Kyōji1981, p. 362). Therefore, unrestricted transactions between the colonies and Japan’s home islands became an issue at the turn of 1944, and currency controls between China and Japan were imposed in March 1944. Critically, however, the controls did not cover Hong Kong and Hainan, the two regions which used military scrip but not CRB and UPBC scrip as their currencies, so some Japanese began transferring their capital in China back to Japan through these two conduits. Transactions from Hong Kong to Japan amounted to 5.4 million yen in 1943 and rose sharply to 10.6 million yen in the first half of 1944. Currency controls were not imposed in Hong Kong and Hainan until November 1944 and February 1945, when Japan’s home islands were already suffering from shortage-induced inflation (Kobayashi and Shibata Reference KOBAYASHI and SHIBATA1996, pp. 206–9).

Japan’s economy was also closely linked to that of Southeast Asia, with Indochina being the largest exporter of rice to Japan in 1943 (Huff Reference HUFF2022 [Reference HUFF2020], p. 134). Further, many of the SDB loans went to zaibatsu-linked companies, such as Asano Heavy Industry, Oji Paper, Japan Sugar Industry, Furukawa Mining Company, Mitsui Bussan, Iwai Industry, Kanegafuchi Industry, Sumitomo Mining Company, and Mitsubishi Corporation.Footnote 23 All of these companies were headquartered in Japan and had branches scattered throughout the empire, meaning that they often remitted colonial currencies (issued as military scrip or military scrip-like currencies) back to Japan.Footnote 24 In December 1944, statistics from the Overseas Capital Bureau of the Ministry of Finance showed that from January to August 1944, remittances (including remittances of corporate profits) from Manchuria, China and Southeast Asia to Japan increased by about 580 million yen over the same period in 1943 (an average of 72 million yen per month), of which 341 million yen came from China, 185 million yen from Manchuria and 51 million yen from Southeast Asia. This was due to inflationary surpluses and anticipation of future exchange rate depreciation against the Japanese yen.Footnote 25 The statistics reflected the flow of military scrip-like currencies into Japan’s home islands, and it was reasonable for the Japanese government to be concerned about this phenomenon. After all, 580 million yen was no small amount, representing 4.68 per cent and 0.6 per cent of its monetary base and money supply (3.18 per cent for M1) in 1943. Moreover, in 1943 Japan ran trade deficits with almost all the regimes in the ‘Greater East Asia Co-Prosperity Sphere’, except Thailand and Burma (Yamamoto Reference YAMAMOTO2011, pp. 118–19). Meanwhile, the nominal value of the monetary base in the colonies continued to grow in 1944 and 1945, being 2.82 times and 4.88 times larger than that in Japan, respectively (Table 5). Since the monetary base was calculated in terms of Japanese yen, the nominal value above has already been adjusted to reflect the exchange rate of the CRB scrip to the yen (1 yen equalled 18 CRB yuan).Footnote 26 Without this adjustment, the gaps between the Japanese and colonial monetary bases would have been even more exaggerated.

The influx of colonial currencies, especially those from occupied China, was discussed in the Diet on 28 January 1945. Kawasaki Katsu asked Finance Minister Ishiwata Sōtarō about the measures to prevent the hyperinflated CRB scrip from contributing to Japan’s inflation, emphasising that Japan ‘is being affected by the price fluctuation of the CRB scrip’. Ishiwata replied:

I will not allow Japan to be affected by the extremely high prices in China, and I will restrict the money made in China from being sent to the interior, and I will restrict such things by what is called ‘exchange control’, as I believe this to be the most effective way of doing so. We are currently exercising very strict controls on currency exchange.Footnote 27

The ‘very strict controls on currency exchange’ referred to the Local Special Measures Deposit System (Genchi tokubetsu sochi yokin seido) which had recently been introduced on 10 January 1945. The system intended to avoid the inflow of funds into Japan as much as possible and to adjust them locally. For repatriated funds over 200,000 yen, three-quarters of the excess was deposited in local currency, and 5,000 yen was paid in cash in Japan. The remainder was sealed as deposits in Japan. The local deposits (the deposits in local currency) were used for loans to the North China Development Corporation, the Central China Development Corporation, and others. Both were national policy companies. The restrictions caused financial difficulties for Japanese in the colonies, leading to measures on March 23 to protect overseas residents’ deposits and allow remittances of up to 10,000 yen for families of conscripts. On 19 April 1945, a Special Deposit System in Foreign Currency (Gaika hyōji Naichi tokubetsu yokinsei) was introduced and foreign currency remittances of repatriated funds were permitted, allowing foreign currency remittances, with part paid in yen and part deposited in local currency (Shibata Reference SHIBATA and Kyōji1981, pp. 362–3).

The draconian currency controls may have been more timely and effective in cutting off the flow of colonial currency to Japan’s home islands, but they also exacerbated the financial difficulties of civilians at home. This was due to the fact that many Japanese worked abroad with families at home and, as mentioned above, some Japanese in the colonies often exchanged the hyperinflated colonial currencies for yen to subsidise the rising cost of living in Japan (Shibata Reference SHIBATA and Kyōji1981, p. 362). In June 1946, Karasawa Toshiko, in her speech to the House of Representatives, cited a survey by the Central Association of Repatriates, stating that 10 million Japanese civilians had been sent to Japan’s colonies since the Manchurian Incident in 1931.Footnote 28 These Japanese remained strongly attached to their homeland, including financially. In December 1945, four months after the war, Nakayama Taichi mentioned in the House of Peers that:

During the war, due to the tightening of foreign exchange controls, the ability to send remittances to families at home was severely restricted. The families left behind in Japan faced considerable hardship, and since the end of the war their situation has worsened. With the complete cessation of remittances since August, these families have lost all sources of income.Footnote 29

In other words, the draconian currency controls imposed eight months before the armistice prevented the hyperinflated colonial currencies from being imported into Japan’s home islands at the cost of cutting off almost all remittances to and from Japan, undermining the financial support and livelihoods of many Japanese civilians. The cessation of cash flow and currency exchange within the Japanese Empire also signified the collapse of the yen bloc.

Therefore, on one hand, the ‘internal financing mechanism’ absorbed civilian wealth and depleted their savings to fuel Japan’s war machine. On the other hand, it created inflationary pressures in Japan’s home islands and hyperinflationary pressures in its colonies, both of which increased the risk of the war financing mechanism’s implosion. Despite efforts to block the influx of colonial hyperinflationary pressures to Japan’s home islands, the strict currency controls cut off almost all remittances. This exacerbated the financial difficulties of civilians at home, disrupted the economy, and eventually led to the break-up of the yen bloc.

IV

In terms of social development, Japan is no longer a thriving country; the war will not lead to the prosperity sought by her ruling classes but to the very reverse, the doom of Japanese imperialism … Japan is a comparatively small country, deficient in manpower and in military, financial, and material resources, and she cannot stand a long war. Japan’s rulers are endeavouring to resolve this difficulty through war, but again they will get the very reverse of what they desire; that is to say, the war they have launched to resolve this difficulty will eventually aggravate it and even exhaust Japan’s original resources.

– Mao Zedong (Reference MAO and Takeuchi1983, pp. 61–2)Footnote 30

In the summer of 1938, Mao was not alone in predicting that Japan would suffer financial hardship as a result of a protracted war with China. As early as February, Cameron Fromanteel Cobbold, the future governor of the Bank of England, said that Yanagita Seijirō, the then superintendent of the BoJ’s London agency, had told him in a telephone conversation that Japanese business circles were ‘anxious about the economic future’, and that they were ‘afraid that Japan’s support of [for] the Provisional Government in North China will prove costly’.Footnote 31 Soon after, Cobbold was informed that the Japanese had approached Swiss banks for loans, but had been turned down.Footnote 32 On 29 June 1938, Irie Sukemasa (Reference IRIE and Irie1994 [Reference IRIE and Irie1990] vol. 1, p. 244), chamberlain (jijū) of the Imperial Household, even claimed in his diary that Japan would go bankrupt if the war could not be ended within the year. Two months later, Kaji Wataru (Reference KAJI1938, p. 16), a Communist and founder of the Japanese People’s Antiwar League, stated in a magazine article published in Jiangxi on 30 August 1938 that Japan’s wealth had already been diminished by one year of total war.Footnote 33 Their views were shared by Westerners. In 1938, Freda Utley, an English political activist still inspired by Marxist and Socialist thought, like almost all foreign commentators, argued that Japan’s lack of capital meant that its war with China could not succeed and would quickly lead to financial disaster and the collapse of the entire production process (Schiltz Reference SCHILTZ2012, pp. 213–14). From late 1938 to early 1940, unaware that the YSB’s New York branch had secretly set up a custody account containing more than one million US dollars in cash and US Treasury securities, US government experts from the State Department, Army Intelligence, and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York boldly predicted that if Japan continued its war with China, its vault would be empty and the country would go bankrupt in one or two years (Miller Reference MILLER2007, pp. 53–5). In March 1941, based on a report from Shanghai, Joseph Goebbels (Reference GOEBBELS and Taylor1982, p. 272), the Reich Minister of Propaganda, wrote in his diary that ‘Japan has got herself stuck, she cannot hold down the huge areas she has already occupied. China is avoiding set-piece battles.’ Contrary to these predictions, which reverberated across the belligerent lines and political spectrums, however, Japan was able to maintain its economic order and financial stability until around mid 1943.

This article shows that Japan’s war economy depended very much on the effectiveness of its ‘internal financial mechanism’. By using civilian capital, the Japanese Empire was able to finance the war effort for a while. However, the consequences of this tactic were costly. As the Japanese government continued to expand its balance sheet by issuing government bonds and printing paper money, it also created inflationary pressures. The government was well aware of the risk, so it attempted to encourage civilians to save in order to minimise the BoJ’s underwriting of government bonds, and also to shift the costs of expansionary monetary and fiscal policies to its colonies by financing military spending with ‘borrowed money’. As shown above, the first tactic failed because the scale of monetary expansion and government bonds issuance outstripped the production capacity. The second tactic had a more serious consequence as it diverted colonial hyperinflationary pressures to the home islands. This failure was rooted in the loose and incomplete currency controls between Japan and other regimes in the yen bloc, with which Japan maintained strong economic and trade links throughout World War II. Although the more effective currency controls were introduced in the final days of the war, they successfully blocked the colonial inflationary pressures imported into Japan’s home islands and also effectively blocked almost all currency exchanges in and out of Japan. This caused financial hardship for civilians at home, disrupted the economy, and led to the collapse of the yen bloc.

Debt financing therefore helped Japan to fight a prolonged war after losing foreign loans and reserves and being sanctioned by the Allies. Paradoxically, the methods used to finance the war also led to the collapse of the empire’s economic order, and eventually, the empire itself. The case of World War II Japan shows that for a government waging total war, (hyper)inflation resulted from debt financing that outpaced the nation’s production capacity, excessive or even unlimited issuance of unbacked currency within the same trading bloc, and loose and incomplete currency controls. In short, all these factors originate from the government’s reliance on unsecured credit. Thus, (hyper)inflation in the wartime Japanese Empire can be considered a monetary phenomenon.

Sources

Bank of England Archives (BoEA)

Diplomatic Archives of the Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Japan

Heung Tao Jih Pao 香島日報

National Archives (United States)

National Archives of Japan (NAJ)

Teikoku gikai kaigiroku kensaku shisutemu 帝国議会会議録検索シ [Imperial Diet Proceedings Search System] (TGKKS)

Glossary

Asano Heavy Industry 浅野重工業株式会社

Ayukawa Gisuke 鮎川義介

Baba Eiichi 馬場鍈一

Bank of Japan (BoJ) 日本銀行

Borrowed money 借入金

Central Association of Repatriates 引揚者団体全国連合会

Central China Development Corporation 中支那振興株式会社

Central Reserve Bank (CRB) 中央儲備銀行

Chamberlain 侍従

Classified income tax 分類所得税

Corporate tax 法人税

Court adviser 御用掛

Deposit Bureau of the Ministry of Finance 大蔵省預金部

Emergency Armaments Expenditure (EAE) 臨時軍事費

Foreign Bureau of the BoJ 日本銀行外事局

Furukawa Mining Company 古河鉱業株式会社

Ichijō Sanetaka 一条実孝

Igarashi Torao 五十嵐虎雄

Imperial Bank 株式会社帝国銀行

Imperial Hotel 株式会社帝国ホテル

Income tax 所得税

Industrial Bank of Japan 株式会社日本興業銀行

Integrated income tax 総合所得税

Invalids’ pension 恩給

Ishiwata Sōtarō 石渡荘太郎

Iwai Industry 株式会社岩井産業

Japan Sugar Industry 日糖興業株式会社

Japanese People’s Antiwar League 日本人民反戦同盟

Kanegafuchi Industry 鐘淵工業株式会社

Karasawa Toshiko 柄沢とし子

Kawada Isao 河田烈

Kawasaki Katsu 川崎克

Kaya Okinori 賀屋興宣

Koiso Kuniaki 小磯国昭

Law on War Supply Companies 軍需会社法

Local Special Measures Deposit System 現地特別措置預金制度

Manchukuo 満州国

Matsumoto Gaku 松本学

Military scrip 軍票

Military scrip-like currencies 軍票類似の通貨

Minister of Finance 大蔵大臣

Ministry of Munitions 軍需省

Mitsubishi Bank 株式会社三菱銀行

Mitsubishi Corporation 三菱商事株式会社

Mitsui Bussan 三井物産株式会社

Nakayama Taichi 中山太一

National policy companies 国策会社

No rice to cook (wu mi ke chui) 無米可炊

North China Development Corporation 北支那開発株式会社

Ogura Masatsune 小倉正恒

Oji Paper 王子製紙株式会社

Ōmoto Sadatarō 大本貞太郎

Overseas Capital Bureau of the Ministry of Finance 大蔵省外資局

Price and Wage Freeze Order 価格等統制令

Prince Takamatsu 高松宮宣仁親王

Privy Councillor 枢密顧問官

Ration coupons 配給券

Regular pension 年金

Sakurauchi Yukio 桜内幸雄

Southern Development Bank (SDB) 南方開発金庫

Special Deposit System in Foreign Currency 外貨表示内地特別預金制

Special yen 特別円

Sugiura Takeo 杉浦武雄

Sumitomo Mining Company 住友鉱業株式会社

Takahashi Korekiyo 高橋是清

Tani Masayuki 谷正之

Temporary Capital Adjustment Act 臨時資金調整法

Temporary income tax 臨時利得税

Tsuchita Yutaka 土田豊

United Preparatory Bank of China (UPBC) 中國聯合準備銀行

Ushio Kenji 牛尾健治

Wang Jingwei regime 汪精衛政權

Wartime Finance Bank 戦時金融金庫

Yanagita Seijirō 柳田誠二郎

Yokohama Specie Bank (YSB) 橫浜正金銀行

Footnotes

1 The average annual inflation rate in Japan’s homeland from December 1931 to August 1945 was 20.65 per cent (22.57 per cent from December 1941 to August 1945) (Table 1). On a monthly basis, wholesale prices in Tokyo rose by 62 per cent between August 1941 and August 1945, while the average monthly inflation rate was merely 2 per cent (Table 6). In Beijing and Shanghai, the financial centres of Northern and Central China, wholesale prices rose by 19,607 and 11,768 per cent respectively from August 1941 to August 1945. The average monthly inflation rate in these two cities was 29 and 126 per cent respectively (Table 6). Thus, only the case of Shanghai falls within Phillip Cagan’s definition of hyperinflation. However, the wholesale price index for Tokyo, Beijing and Shanghai only reflected the movement of official prices, not black market prices, especially in Japan, where price controls were introduced in the late 1930s. The diaries of Hosokawa Morisada and Nagai Kafū show that between February 1944 and February 1945 the black market price of sugar had increased between 4.5 and 7.5 times. Hosokawa (Reference HOSOKAWA1953), vol. 1, pp. 137–8; Nagai (Reference NAGAI1981), vol. 6, p. 11. For Cagan’s definition, see Cagan (Reference CAGAN and Friedman1956), pp. 25–117.

2 This argument was inspired by Thomas J. Sargent’s (Reference SARGENT and Hall1983 [Reference SARGENT and Hall1982], pp. 89–90) analysis of the end of hyperinflations.

3 This argument was inspired by Ben S. Bernanke’s (Reference BERNANKE and Bernanke2024 [Reference BERNANKE and Bernanke2004], pp. 41–69) research on how bank panics during the Great Depression disrupted normal credit flows, which could affect the performance of the real economy.

4 For an overview of the development of the Japanese Empire and the economic and industrial activities in its colonies, see Yamamoto (Reference YAMAMOTO2011), pp. 33–44; Hara (Reference HARA2013), pp. 89–138; Donzé and Yongue (Reference DONZÉ and YONGUE2024), pp. 106–23.

5 For a review of the literature published from the 1940s to the early 1990s on Japan’s colonial currencies (including military scrip and scrip-like currencies), see Kobayashi (Reference KOBAYASHI2012), pp. 102–3.

6 Itō Sei, a novelist and translator of English literature, wrote in his diary on 24 June 1944 that ‘If Japan loses its sea power, we will be blockaded on this island nation, and hundreds of thousands, even millions of soldiers stationed in Burma, other Southern occupied territories, and frontline positions, will be isolated and cut off from supplies. What would become of us?’ Tamura Tsunejirō, an ordinary Kyoto man, mentioned in his diary on 19 July 1944 that ‘Japan would probably be defeated (by food shortages).’ Itō (Reference ITŌ1983), vol. 3, pp. 42–3; Yamashita (Reference YAMASHITA2005), pp. 83–4. See also ‘Johnston Committee report: economic position of Japan and Korea’, May 1948 (US Army), MS Records of the Far Eastern Commission, 1945–1952, National Archives (United States); Ruge (Reference RUGE and Saunders1957), pp. 376–83; Hayashi (Reference HAYASHI1962), pp. 144–54; Moore (Reference MOORE2018), p. 211; Adachi (Reference ADACHI2022), pp. 161–97, 211–18; Garon (Reference GARON2024), pp. 535–50.

7 See also Tables 5a, 5b.

8 ‘Dai 74-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin yosan iinkai kaigiroku (sokki) dai 20-kai Shōwa 14-nen 3-gatsu 9-nichi 第74回帝国議会衆議院予算委員会会議録(速記)第20回 昭和14年3月9日’, Teikoku gikai kaigiroku kensaku shisutemu [henceforth TGKKS], https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=007413541X02019390309

9 ‘Dai 76-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin yosan iinkai kaigiroku (sokki) dai 6-kai Shōwa 16-nen 1-gatsu 27-nichi 第76回帝国議会衆議院予算委員会会議録 (速記) 第6回 昭和16年1月27日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=007613541X00619410127

10 ‘Dai 81-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin giji sokkiroku dai 5-gō Shōwa 18-nen 1-gatsu 29-nichi 第81回帝国議会衆議院議事速記録第5号 昭和18年1月29日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=008113242X00519430129

11 ‘Dai 86-kai teikoku gikai kizokuin Shōwa 20-nendo ippan kaikei saishutsu no zaigen ni mitsuru-tō no tame no kōsai hakkō ni kansuru hōritsuan tokubetsu iinkai giji sokki dai 2-gō Shōwa 20-nen 1-gatsu 30-nichi 第86回帝国議会貴族院昭和二十年度一般会計歳出の財源に充つる等の為の公債発行に関する法律案特別委員会議事速記第2号 昭和20年1月30日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=008601747X00219450130

12 ‘Dai 75-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin shotokuzeihō kaisei hōritsuan gai sanjūken iinkai kaigiroku (sokki) dai 13-kai Shōwa 15-nen 3-gatsu 1-nichi 第75回帝国議会衆議院所得税法改正法律案外三十件 委員会会議録 (速記) 第13回 昭和15年3月1日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=007511581X01319400301

13 ‘Dai 76-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin yosan iinkai (sokki) dai 16-kai Shōwa 16-nen 2-gatsu 15-nichi 第76回帝国議会衆議院予算委員会 (速記) 第16回 昭和16年2月15日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=007613541X01619410215

14 ‘Dai 81-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin giji sokkiroku dai 5-gō Shōwa 18-nen 1-gatsu 29-nichi.’

15 ‘Dai 74-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin yosan iinkai kaigiroku (sokki) dai 9-kai Shōwa 14-nen 2-gatsu 1-nichi 第74回帝国議会衆議院予算委員会会議録 (速記) 第9回 昭和14年2月1日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=007413541X00919390201

16 Most of the government bonds issued in the fiscal years 1936 to 1944 were 3.5% bonds with maturities ranging from 10 to 17 years. Ōkurashō Shōwa zaiseishi henshūshitsu (1954), pp. 46–61 [in appendix].

17 For the amount of government bonds and the Deposit Bureau’s deposits, Table 3 and Sekino (Reference SEKINO2021), p. 188.

18 For example, the aforementioned speeches by Sakurauchi Yukio in March 1940 and Kawada Isao in February 1941 before the House of Representatives.

19 ‘Dai 71-kai teikoku gikai kizokuin giji sokuroku kiroku dai 4-gō Shōwa 12-nen 7-gatsu 29-nichi 第71回帝国議会貴族院議事速録記録第4号 昭和12年7月29日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=007103242X00419370729&current=1

20 Ushio Kenji, head of the Ushio zaibatsu, held a wedding banquet for his eldest daughter at the Imperial Hotel in January 1944 with over 200 guests, which was described as ‘a rare occasion under the present circumstances’. Lin Hsien-t’ang, a businessman in colonial Taiwan who was appointed to the House of Peers in March 1945, stated in his diary on 24 November 1944 that he had ‘no rice to cook’ (wu mi ke chui), probably due to the stricter distribution system at a time of food shortage. Another member of the House of Peers, Matsumoto Gaku, mentioned in June 1945 that all his colleagues seemed to have slimmed down, in which Prince Ichijō Sanetaka had become a different person. In August 1945, there was even a report from occupied Hong Kong that a couple had been arrested for eating and selling meat from corpses found on the streets. ‘Sheng ren shi siren 生人食死人’,Heung Tao Jih Pao, no. 1128 (9 August 1945), p. 2; Lin (Reference LIN and HSU2008), vol. 16, p. 388; Shōyu kurabu (Reference KURABU2021), pp. 260, 378–9.

21 The agreements between the YSB and the CRB were included in ‘Yokohama Shōkin Ginkō, Chōsen Ginkō oyobi Chūgoku Rengō Junbi Ginkō-kan kakushu keiyakusho narabi ni kankei bunsho 横浜正金銀行・朝鮮銀行及中国連合準備銀行間各種契約書並に関係文書’, JACAR Ref.A17110614700, Sengo zaiseishi shiryō Sakai (Makoto) bunsho en’iki hakken ginkō (Shōwa 17 nen – 18 nen): Doitsu, Itarī, Futsuin to no ginkōkan kyōtei tai-Shi kawase mondai (Shōwa 20 nen) Dai 19 gō 戦後財政史資料 酒井 (誠) 文書 円域発券銀行 (昭和17年∼18年)・ドイツ、イタリー、仏印との銀行間協定対支為替問題 (昭和20年) 第19号 (National Archives of Japan).

22 ‘Dai-3-kai sensō keizai chitsujo kakuho ni kansuru kenkyūkai Nihon Ginkō Gaijikyoku Igarashi Tōa dai-1 kakachō kōwa yōshi (ichibu) 第3回戦争経済秩序確保に関する研究会 日本銀行外事局五十嵐東亜第1課長講話要旨 (一部’, JACAR Ref. A18110425500, Shōwa zaiseishi shiryō dai 9-gō sensō keizai zaisei kin’yū seisaku (6) (Shō 17-20) 昭和財政史資料 第9号 戦時経済 財政金融政策(6) (昭・17-20) (National Archives of Japan).

23 ‘Nanpō Kaihatsu Kinko jigyō hōkokusho/ bunkatsu ichi 南方開発金庫事業報告書/分割1’, JACAR Ref. B06050433500, Nanpō Kaihatsu Kinko jigyō hōkokusho 南方開発金庫事業報告書 (E173) (Diplomatic Archives of the Ministry of Foreign Affairs).

24 For example, Mitsui Bussan was headquartered in Tokyo, and had 8 branches at home, 2 in Taiwan, 2 in Korea, 8 in Manchukuo, 8 under the Wang Jingwei regime, 1 in Mengjiang and 10 in Southeast Asia. Shōken hikiuke kaisha tōseikaihen (1944), p. 414.

25 ‘Kyōeiken (Manshū Shina oyobi Nanpō) yori no honkoku e no sōkin jōkyō 共栄圏 (満洲支那及南方) よりの本邦への送金情況’, JACAR Ref. A17110569600, Sengo zaiseishi shiryō Sakai (Makoto) bunsho gaishikyoku kawasekankei bunsho 6 Shōwa 19 nen Dai 7 gō 戦後財政史資料 酒井 (誠) 文書 外資局為替関係文書6 昭和19年 第7号 (National Archives of Japan).

26 Except for the CRB scrip, the exchange rates between the Japanese yen and other colonial currencies, including military scrip and the military scrip-like currencies were 1:1.

27 ‘Dai 86-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin yosan iin dai 3 bunka (ōkurashō oyobi monbushō shokan) kaigiroku (sokki) dai 1-kai Shōwa 20-nen 1-gatsu 28-nichi 第86回帝国議会衆議院予算委員第三分科 (大蔵省及文部省所管) 会議録 (速記) 第1回 昭和20年1月28日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=008613587X00119450128&spkNum

28 ‘Dai 90-kai teikoku gikai shūgiin giji sokkiroku dai 9-gō Shōwa 21-nen 6-gatsu 30-nichi 第90回帝国議会衆議院議事速記録第9号 昭和21年6月30日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=009013242X00919460629&spkNum=31

29 ‘Dai 89-kai teikoku gikai kizokuin yosan iinkai giji sokkiroku dai 2-gō Shōwa 20-nen 12-gatsu 14-nichi 第89回帝国議会貴族院予算委員会議事速記録第2号 昭和20年12月14日’, TGKKS, https://teikokugikai-i.ndl.go.jp/#/detail?minId=008903541X00219451214&spkNum=6

30 There are at least two publicly available versions of this essay, the first written in 1938 and the second in 1952. The 1938 version is collected in the Mo Takuto shu. The essay’s content was first presented by Mao in a series of speeches from 26 May to 3 June, and after revisions it was published on 1 July. The English translation here was borrowed from the Selected Works of Mao Tse-Tung, which was translated from the Chinese version of the same book published in 1960, and the essay collected in that volume was the 1952 version. However, there is no difference between the 1938 and 1952 versions in terms of the lines quoted above (Mao Reference MAO1965, p. 122).

31 ‘A Cameron Fromanteel Cobbold Memorandum’, 7/2/1938, Bank of England Archive [henceforth BoEA], Ov16/4.

32 ‘A Cameron Fromanteel Cobbold Memorandum’, 13/2/1938, BoEA, Ov16/4.

33 Although Kaji’s writing was a piece of anti-war propaganda, he rightly pointed out that the Japanese wealth was beginning to dwindle. This was evidenced by the amount of EAE in the fiscal year 1937, which amounted to 2.034 billion yen, 69.8 per cent of the annual income that year, and 85.8 per cent of the income in 1936 (Sekino Reference SEKINO2021, pp. 35, 38).

References

ACEMOGLU, D. and ROBINSON, J. A. (2012). Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty. London: Profile Books.Google Scholar
ADACHI, H. 安達宏昭 (2022). Daitōa kyōeiken: Teikoku Nihon no Ajia shihaikōsō 大東亜共栄圏:帝国日本のアジア支配構想 [The Greater East Asia Co-Prosperity Sphere: Imperial Japan’s Vision for Asian Domination]. Tokyo: Chūōkōron shinsha.Google Scholar
ANDŌ, Y. 安藤良雄 (1979). Ryōtaisengan no Nihon shihonshugi: Sono rekishi no gaikan 両大戦間の日本資本主義: その歴史の概観 [Japan’s Capitalism Between the Two World Wars: An Overview of its History]. In Andō, Y. (ed.), Ryōtaisengan no Nihon shihonshugi 両大戦間の日本資本主義 [Japan’s Capitalism Between the Two World Wars]. Tokyo: Tōkyō daigaku shuppankai.Google Scholar
AOKI, T. 青木得三 (1943). Senshi o umu chikara 戦費を生む力 [Ability to Generate War Spending]. Tokyo: Taisei yokusankai sendenbu.Google Scholar
BARNHART, M. A. (1987). Japan Prepares for Total War: The Search for Economic Security, 1919–1941. Ithaca, NY, and London: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
BAXTER, J. (2007). Japanese private sector banks, 1931–1945: a business perspective. Japan Review, 19, pp. 161214.Google Scholar
BERNANKE, B. S. (2024 [2004]). Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the Great Depression. In Bernanke, B. S., Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
CAGAN, P. (1956). The monetary dynamics of hyperinflation. In Friedman, M. (ed.), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
CHENG, H. S. 鄭會欣 (2024). Huabei lunxian shiqi de huobi yu jinrong 華北淪陷時期的貨幣與金融 [Money and finance in occupied northern China]. In Cheng, H. S., Yanxu yu biange: Minguo jingji shi xilun 延續與變革: 民國經濟史析論 [Continuity and Change: An Analysis of the Economic History in the Republican Era]. Hong Kong: Chung Hwa Book (HK).Google Scholar
COHEN, J. B. (1949). Japan’s Economy in War and Reconstruction. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota.Google Scholar
CROWLEY, J. B. (1966). Japan’s Quest for Autonomy: National Security and Foreign Policy, 1930–1938. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
DAVIS, L. E. and HUTTENBACK, R. A. (1986). Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire: The Political Economy of British Imperialism, 1860–1912. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
DONZÉ, P.-Y. and YONGUE, J. S. (2024). Japanese Capitalism and Entrepreneurship: A History of Business from the Tokugawa Era to the Present. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
FUKAI, E. 深井英五 (1953). Sūmitsu-in jūyō giji oboegaki 枢密院重要議事覚書 [Memorandum on Important Matters of the Privy Council]. Tokyo: Iwanami shōten.Google Scholar
GARON, S. (2012). Beyond Our Means: Why America Spends While the World Saves. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
GARON, S. (2024). Operation STARVATION, 1945: A transnational history of blockades and the defeat of Japan. The International History Review, 46(4), pp. .CrossRefGoogle Scholar
GOEBBELS, J. (1982). The Goebbels Diaries, 1939–1941, ed. and trans. Taylor, F.. London: Hamish Hamilton.Google Scholar
HARA, A. 原朗 (2000 [1998]). Japan: guns before rice. In Harrison, M. (ed.), The Economics of World War II: Six Great Powers in International Comparison. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
HARA, A. (2013) Nihon senji keizai kenkyū 日本戦時経済研究 [Research on Japan’s Wartime Economy]. Tokyo: Tōkyō daigaku shuppankai.Google Scholar
HAYASHI, S. 林茂 et al. (eds.) (1962). Nihon shūsenshi jōkan: 8 gatsu 15 nichi no tādetā: hoka 日本終戦史. 上巻 八月十五日のクーデター: ほか [History of Japan’s End of the War, vol. I: The August 15 Coup d’État and Others]. Tokyo: Yomiuri shinbunsha.Google Scholar
HIKITA, Y. 疋田康行 et al. (eds.) (1995). ‘Nanpō kyōeiken’: Senji Nihon no Tōnan Ajia keizai shihai「南方共栄圏」: 戦時日本の東南アジア経済支配 [‘Southern Co-prosperity Sphere’: Wartime Japan’s Economic Domination of Southeast Asia]. Tokyo: Taga shuppan.Google Scholar
HIRAI, K. 平井健介 (2017). Nihon teikoku-nai ni okeru bungyō to sōkoku: Seitōgyō o jirei ni 日本帝国内における分業と相剋: 製糖業を事例に [Division of Labour and Rivalry Within the Japanese Empire: The Case of the Sugar Industry.]. Shakai keizaishi gaku, 83(1), pp. 2947.Google Scholar
HOLTFRERICH, C.-L. (1986). The German Inflation 1914–1923: Causes and Effects in International Perspective, trans Balderston, T.. Berlin and New York: Walter de Gruyter.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
HOSOKAWA, M. 細川護貞 (1953). Jōhō Tennō ni tassezu: Hosokawa nikki 情報天皇に達せず: 細川日記 [The Information Did Not Reach the Emperor: The Diary of Hosokawa]. Tokyo: Isobe shobō.Google Scholar
HUFF, G. (2017 [2015]). Finance for war in Asia and its aftermath. In Geyer, M. and Tooze, A. (eds.), The Cambridge History of the Second World War, vol. III: Total War: Economy, Society and Culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
HUFF, G. (2022 [2020]). World War II and Southeast Asia: Economy and Society under Japanese Occupation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
HUFF, G. and MAJIMA, S. 眞嶋史叙 (2013). Financing Japan’s World War II occupation of Southeast Asia. The Journal of Economic History, 73, pp. .CrossRefGoogle Scholar
INOUE, H. 井上晴丸 and USAMI, S. 宇佐美誠次郎 (1951). Kiki ni okeru Nihon shihonshugi no kōzō 危機における日本資本主義の構造 [The Structure of Japan’s Capitalism in Crisis]. Tokyo: Iwanami shoten.Google Scholar
IRIE, S. 入江相政 (1994 [1990]). Irie Sukemasa nikki 入江相政日記 [Diary of Irie Sukemasa], gen. ed. Irie, T. 入江為年. Tokyo: Asahi shinbunsha.Google Scholar
ISHII, K. 石井寛治 (2012). Teikokushugi Nihon no taigai senryaku 帝国主義日本の対外戦略 [Foreign Strategy of Imperialist Japan]. Nagoya: Nagoya daigaku shuppanka.Google Scholar
ITŌ, M. 伊藤正直 (1994). Zaisei kin’yū 財政·金融 [Fiscal Policy and Finance]. In Oishi, K. 大石嘉一郎 (ed.), Nippon teikoku shugishi 3 Dai ni ji taisenki 日本帝国主義史 3 第二次大戦期 [History of Japanese Imperialism, vol. 3: World War II]. Tokyo: Tōkyō daigaku shuppankai.Google Scholar
ITŌ, S. 伊藤整 (1983). Taiheiyō sensō nikki 太平洋戦争日記 [Diary of the Pacific War]. Tokyo: Shinchōsha.Google Scholar
KAJI, W. 鹿地亘 (1938). Dadao Ri fa de wangguo zhengche 打倒日閥的亡國政策 [Down with the Japanese warlords’ policy of extermination]. Zhengzhi qingbao, 20, pp. 1516.Google Scholar
KANEKO, F. 金子文夫 (1994). Shokuminchi senryōchi shihai 植民地·占領地支配 [Dominating Colonial and Occupied Territories]. In Oishi, K. (ed.), Nippon teikoku shugishi 3 Dai ni ji taisenki 日本帝国主義史 3 第二次大戦期 [History of Japanese Imperialism, vol. 3: World War II]. Tokyo: Tōkyō daigaku shuppankai.Google Scholar
KATANO, I. 片野一郎 (1946). Infurēshon kaikei no jisshōteki kenkyū: Shanhai infurēshon o chūshin ni shite インフレーション会計の実証的研究: 上海インフレーションを中心にして [An Empirical Study of Inflation Accounting: With a Focus on Shanghai Inflation]. Tokyo: Sangyō tosho kabushiki gaisha.Google Scholar
KOBAYASHI, H. 小林英夫 (1993). Nihon gunseika no Ajia: ‘Daitōa Kyōeiken’ to gunpyō 日本軍政下のアジア: 「大東亜共栄圏」と軍票 [Asia Under Japan’s Military Occupation: The ‘Greater East Asia Co-prosperity Sphere’ and Military Scrip]. Tokyo: Iwanami shoten.Google Scholar
KOBAYASHI, H. 小林英夫 (2012). ‘Dai Tōa kyōeiken’ to Nihon kigyō「大東亜共栄圏」と日本企業 [The Greater East Asia Co-Prosperity Sphere and Japanese Enterprise]. Tokyo: Shakai hyōronsha.Google Scholar
KOBAYASHI, H. and SHIBATA, Y 柴田善雅 (1996). Nihon gunseika no Honkon 日本軍政下の香港 [Hong Kong Under Japanese Military Occupation]. Tokyo: Shakai hyōronsha.Google Scholar
LEE, Y.-P. 李宇平 (2004). 1930 niandai chuqi Dongya quyu jingji zhongxin de bianhua – Riben kuozhang shuchu yu Zhongguo jingji xiaotiao 1930 年代初期東亞區域經濟重心的變化 – 日本擴張輸出與中國經濟蕭條 [The transformation of East Asia’s economic core during the early 1930s: Japan’s expanded exports and China’s economic depression]. Bulletin of the Institute of Modern History Academia Sinica, 43, pp. 57116.Google Scholar
LIN, H.-T. 林獻堂 (2008), Guanyuan xiansheng riji 灌園先生日記 [Diary of Lin Hsien-t’ang], ed. HSU, H.-C. 許雪姬.Taipei: Institute of Taiwan History and Institute of Modern History, Academia Sinica.Google Scholar
LOCKWOOD, W. W. (1974 [1968]). The Economic Development of Japan: Growth and Structural Change (expanded edition). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
MAO, T.-T. 毛澤東 (1965). Selected Works of Mao Tse-Tung, vol. 2. Peking: Foreign Language Press.Google Scholar
MAO, Z. (1983). Lun chijiu zhan 論持久戰 [On Protracted War]. In Takeuchi, M. 竹内実 gen (ed.), Mo Takuto shu 毛沢東集 [Collected Works of Mao Zedong], rev. edn, vol. 6. Tokyo: Sososha.Google Scholar
MATSUMOTO, T. 松本俊郎 (1988). Shinryaku to kaihatsu: Nihon shihonshugi to Chūgoku shokuminchika 侵略と開発: 日本資本主義と中国植民地化 [Invasion and Development: Japan’s Capitalism and the Colonisation of China]. Tokyo: Ochanomizu shobō.Google Scholar
METZLER, M. (2006). Lever of Empire: The International Gold Standard and the Crisis of Liberalism in Prewar Japan. Berkeley and London: University of California Press.Google Scholar
MILLER, E. S. (2007). Bankrupting the Enemy: The U.S. Financial Siege of Japan before Pearl Harbor. Annapolis, MD: Naval Institute Press.Google Scholar
MOORE, A. W. (2018). Bombing the City: Civilian Accounts of the Air War in Britain and Japan, 1939–1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MYERS, R. H. (1996). Creating a modern enclave economy: the economic integration of Japan, Manchuria, and North China, 1932–1945. In Duus, P., Myers, R. H. and Peattie, M. R. (eds.), The Japanese Wartime Empire, 1931–1945. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
NAGAI, K. 永井荷風 (1981). Danchō-tei nichijō 斷腸亭日乘 [Diary of Nagai Kafū]. Tokyo: Iwanami shōten.Google Scholar
NAKAMURA, T. (1996). The Yen Bloc, 1931–1945. In Duus, P., Myers, R. H. and Peattie, M. R. (eds.), The Japanese Wartime Empire, 1931–1945. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
NAKAMURA, T. 中村隆英 (1999 [1994]). Lectures on Modern Japanese Economic History 1926–1994. Tokyo: LTCB International Library Foundation.Google Scholar
NIHON GINKŌ CHŌSAKYOKU TOKUBETSU CHŌSASHITSU 日本銀行調査局特別調査室 (1948). Manshū jihen igo no zaisei kin’yūshi 満州事変以後の財政金融史 [Financial and Economic History After the Manchurian Incident]. Tokyo: Nihon ginkō chōsakyoku tokubetsu chōsashitsu.Google Scholar
NOLTE, S. H. (1987). Liberalism in Modern Japan: Ishibashi Tanzan and His Teachers, 1905–1960. Berkeley and London: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OKAZAKI, T. 岡崎哲二 and OKUNO-FUJIWARA, M. 奥野正寛 (2002 [1999]). Japan’s present-day economic system and its historical origins. In Okazaki, T. and Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (eds.), The Japanese Economic System and Its Historical Origins. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
ŌKURASHŌ SHŌWA ZAISEISHI HENSHŪSHITSU 大蔵省昭和財政史編集室 (ed.) (1954). Shōwa zaiseishi dai 6-kan kokusai 昭和財政史 第6卷 国債 [The Shōwa Financial History, vol. 6, National Debt]. Tokyo: Tōyō keizai shinpōsha.Google Scholar
ŌKURASHŌ SHŌWA ZAISEISHI HENSHŪSHITSU (ed.) (1955). Shōwa zaiseishi dai 4-kan rinji gunjihi 昭和財政史 第4卷 臨時軍事費 [The Shōwa Financial History, vol. 4, Emergency Armaments Expenditure]. Tokyo: Tōyō keizai shinpōsha.Google Scholar
ŌKURASHŌ SHŌWA ZAISEISHI HENSHŪSHITSU (ed.) (1956). Shōwa zaiseishi dai 9-kan tōka・bukka 昭和財政史 第9卷 通貨・物価 [The Shōwa Financial History, vol. 9, Currency and Prices]. Tokyo: Tōyō keizai shinpōsha.Google Scholar
ŌKURASHŌ SHŌWA ZAISEISHI HENSHŪSHITSU (ed.) (1965). Shōwa zaiseishi dai 1-kan sōsetsu 昭和財政史 第1卷 総説 [The Shōwa Financial History, vol. 1, Overview]. Tokyo: Tōyō keizai shinpōsha.Google Scholar
ŌKURASHŌ 大蔵省 and NIHON GINKŌ 日本銀行 (eds.) (1948). Zaisei keizai tōkei nenpō Shōwa 23-nen 財政経済統計年報 昭和23年 [Annual Report of Financial and Economic Statistics, 1948]. Tokyo: Ōkurazaimu kyōkai.Google Scholar
ONO, K. 小野圭司 (2022 [2021]). Nihon sensō keizaishi: Senpi, tsūka kinyū seisaku, kokusai hikaku 日本戦争経済史: 戦費、通貨金融政策、国際比較 [History of Japan’s War Economy: War Expenditures, Monetary and Financial Policies, and International Comparison]. Tokyo: Nikkei Business Publications.Google Scholar
ŌUCHI, H. 大内兵衛 (1949 [1947]). Kokumin seikatsu to zaisei 国民生活と財政 [National Life and Public Finance]. Tokyo: Iwanami shoten.Google Scholar
REINHART, C. M. and ROGOFF, K. S. (2009). This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
REVELANT, A. (2015). Growth strategy and war: tax dilemmas for Japan’s Finance Ministry in the 1930s. Asiatische Studien, 69(2), pp. .Google Scholar
RUGE, F. (1957) Der Seekrieg: The German Navy’s Story, 1939–1945, trans Saunders, M. G.. Annapolis: United States Navy Institute.Google Scholar
SAITŌ, E. 斎藤栄三郎 (1949). Taiheiyō senki ni okeru Nihon keizai no kenkyū: 1941–1945 太平洋戦期における日本経済の研究: 1941–1945 [Research on the Japanese economy during the Pacific War, 1941–1945]. Tokyo: Waseda shuppansha.Google Scholar
SANWA, R. 三和良一 and HARA, A. (2021 [2010]). Kingendai Nihon keizaishi yōran (hoteiban) 近現代日本経済史要覧(補訂版) [Handbook of Modern and Contemporary Japanese Economic History (rev. edn)]. Tokyo: Tōkyō daigaku shuppankai.Google Scholar
SARGENT, T. J. (1983 [1982]). The ends of four big inflations. In Hall, R. E. (ed.), Inflation: Causes and Effects. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
SCHILTZ, M. (2012). The Money Doctors from Japan: Finance, Imperialism, and the Building of the Yen Bloc, 1895–1937. Cambridge, MA, and London: Harvard University Asia Center.Google Scholar
SEKINO, M. 関野満夫 (2021). Nihon no sensō zaisei - Nichi Chū sensō, Ajia Taiheiyō sensō no zaisei bunseki 日本の戦争財政—日中戦争・アジア太平洋戦争の財政分析 [Japan’s War Finance: A Financial Analysis of the Sino-Japanese and Asia-Pacific Wars]. Tokyo: Chūō daigaku shuppanbu.Google Scholar
SEOW, V. 蕭建業 (2021). Carbon Technocracy: Energy Regimes in Modern East Asia. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
SHIBATA, Y. (1981). Nihon teikoku shugi ni yoru Chūgoku senryōchi no tsūka kinyū kōsaku 日本帝国主義による中国占領地の通貨金融工作 [Currency and financial operations in occupied China under Japanese imperialism]. In Kyōji, A. 浅田喬二 (ed.), Nihon teikoku shugi-ka no Chūgoku: Chūgoku senryōchi keizai no kenkyū 日本帝国主義下の中国: 中国占領地経済の研究 [China Under Japanese Imperialism: A Study of Occupied China’s Economy]. Tokyo: Rakuyū shobō.Google Scholar
SHIBATA, Y. (2011). Senji Nihon no kin’yū tōsei: Shihon shijō to kaisha keiri 戦時日本の金融統制: 資本市場と会社経理 [Financial Control in Wartime Japan: Capital Markets and Company Accounting]. Tokyo: Nihon keizai hyōronsha.Google Scholar
SHŌKEN HIKIUKE KAISHA TŌSEIKAIHEN 証券引受会社統制会 (ed.) (1944). Kabushikigaisha nenkan Shōwa 19 nenban 株式会社年報 昭和十九年版 [Annual Report of Joint-Stock Companies, 1944 edition]. Tokyo: Shōken hikiuke kaisha tōseikaihen.Google Scholar
KURABU, SHŌYU 尚友俱楽部 et al. (eds.) (2021). Matsumoto Gaku nikki (Shōwa 14 nen-22 nen) 松本学日記 (昭和十四年-二十二年)[Diary of Matsumoto Gaku, 1939–1947]. Tokyo: Fuyō shobō.Google Scholar
SMETHURST, R. J. (2007). From Foot Soldier to Finance Minister: Takahashi Korekiyo, Japan’s Keynes. Cambridge, MA, and London: Harvard University Asia Center.Google Scholar
TAKAISHI, S. 高石末吉 (1960). Oboegaki shūsen zaisei shimatsu dai yon kan senpi no chōtatsu to gaichi ginkō 覚書終戦財政始末 第4巻 戦費の調達と外地銀行 [Memorandum on Finance at the End of World War II, vol. 4, Financing of War Expenditures and Foreign Banks]. Tokyo: Okurashō daijin kanbō chōsaka.Google Scholar
TAKEDA, H. 武田晴人 (2020). Zaibatsu no jidai 財閥の時代 [The Age of Zaibatsu]. Tokyo: KADOKAWA.Google Scholar
TAKEDA, H. (2024). Nihon teikokushugi no keizō kōzō 日本帝国主義の経済構造 [Economic Structure of Japan’s Imperialism]. Tokyo: Tōkyō daigaku shuppankai.Google Scholar
TANNO, I. 丹野勲 (2017). Nihon kigyō no Tōnanajia shinshutsu no rūtsu to senryaku: Senzenki Nanyō de no kokusai keiei to Nihonjin imin no rekishi 日本企業の東南アジア進出のルーツと戦略: 戦前期南洋での国際経営と日本人移民の歴史 [Roots and Strategies of Japanese Corporate Expansion in Southeast Asia: The Pre-World War II International Management and Japanese Immigration to the South Seas]. Tokyo: Dobunkan.Google Scholar
TATAI, Y. 多田井喜生 (2020 [2002]). Chōsen ginkō: Aru en tsūkaken no kōbō 朝鮮銀行: ある円通貨圏の興亡 [Bank of Chōsen: The Rise and Fall of a Yen-Based Currency Bloc]. Tokyo: Chikuma shobō.Google Scholar
TERANISHI, J. 寺西重郎 (2002 [1999]). The main bank system. In Okazaki, T. and Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (eds.), The Japanese Economic System and Its Historical Origins. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
TOOZE, A. and MARTIN, J. (2017 [2015]). The economics of the war with Nazi Germany. In Geyer, M. and Tooze, A. (eds.), The Cambridge History of the Second World War, vol. III: Total War: Economy, Society and Culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
UDAGAWA, M. 宇田川勝 (2001). The move into Manchuria of the Nissan combine. In Tolliday, S. (ed.), The Economic Development of Modern Japan, 1898–1945: From the Meiji Restoration to the Second World War, vol. II. Cheltenham and Northampton: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
UEDA, K. 植田和男 (2002 [1999]). The financial system and its regulations. In Okazaki, T. and Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (eds.), The Japanese Economic System and Its Historical Origins. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
UGAKI, K.宇垣一成 (1971). Ugaki Kazushige nikki 宇垣一成日記 [Diary of Ugaki Kazushige. Tokyo: Misuzu shobō.Google Scholar
YAMAMOTO, Y. 山本有造 (2011). ‘Dai Tōa kyōeiken’ keizaishi kenkyū「大東亜共栄圈」経済史研究 [Research on the Economic History of the ‘Greater East Asia Co-Prosperity Sphere’]. Nagoya: Nagoya daigaku shuppanka.Google Scholar
YAMASHITA, S. (2005). Leaves from an Autumn of Emergencies. Honolulu: University of Hawai’i Press.Google Scholar
YANAGISAWA, Y. 柳沢遊 (2018). Nihon teikoku shugi shiron 日本帝国主義史論 [Study on the History of Japanese Imperialism]. In Asai, Y. 浅井良夫 et al. (eds.), Nakamura Masanori no rekishigaku 中村正則の歴史学 [The Historiography of Nakamura Masanori]. Tokyo: Nihon keizai hyōronsha.Google Scholar
ZHOU, F. 周佛海 (2003). Zhou Fohai riji quanbian 周佛海日記全編 [Completed Diary of Zhou Fohai]. Beijing: Zhongguo wenlian chuban she.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1a. Japan’s monetary base, money supply, interest rate and inflation measures (1931–45.8) (in thousands of yen)

Figure 1

Table 1b. Japan’s monetary base, money supply, interest rate and inflation measures (1931–45.8) (in thousands of yen)

Figure 2

Table 1c. Japan’s monetary base, money supply, interest rate, and inflation measures (1931–45.8) (in thousands of yen)

Figure 3

Table 2. Money supply in Japan (M1) (1931–45.8) (in thousands of yen)

Figure 4

Table 3. Japan’s nominal GNP, the amount of government bonds, and government’s revenue and expenditure (in thousands of yen) (1931–44)

Figure 5

Table 4. Japan’s national income, tax revenue and taxes per capita (1931–44) (national income and tax revenue: in thousands of yen; population: in thousands)

Figure 6

Table 5a. The monetary base and money supply in the Japanese Colonies (1941–5.8) (in thousands of yen)

Figure 7

Table 5b. The monetary base and money supply in the Japanese Colonies (1941–5.8) (in thousands of yen)

Figure 8

Table 5c. The monetary base and money supply in the Japanese colonies (1941–5.8) (in thousands of yen)

Figure 9

Table 6. Monthly wholesale prices and inflation in Tokyo, Beijing and Shanghai (1941.8–1945.8)