Hostname: page-component-6bb9c88b65-znhjv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-07-25T13:32:49.397Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Cross of Gold: Brazilian Treasure and the Decline of Portugal

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 July 2025

Davis Kedrosky
Affiliation:
Ph.D. Economics, Northwestern University, 2211 Campus Dr., Evanston, IL 60208. E-mail: dkedrosky@u.northwestern.edu.
Nuno Palma*
Affiliation:
Professor, University of Manchester, Oxford Rd, Manchester M13 9PL, United Kingdom.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

As late as 1750, Portugal had a high output per head by Western European standards. Yet just a century later, Portugal was this region’s poorest country. In this paper, we show that the discovery of massive quantities of gold in Brazil over the eighteenth century played a key role in the long-run development of Portugal. The country suffered from an economic and political resource curse. A counterfactual based on synthetic control methods suggests that by 1800 Portugal’s GDP per capita was 40 percent lower than it would have been without its endowment of Brazilian gold.

Information

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association

The Little Divergence in early modern Europe is a well-documented phase of economic history, but the causes of Northwestern Europe’s surge ahead remain controversial (Broadberry Reference Broadberry2021a, 2021b). An influential tradition, dating back to the work of North and Weingast (Reference North and Weingast1989), attributes English success to institutional change: the development of a semi-representative democracy and constrained executive. Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2005) also foreground the state, arguing that pre-1500 political institutions interacted with the rise of Atlantic trade to produce a pro-growth political environment in England and the Netherlands, but not Spain and Portugal. Limited Anglo-Dutch polities are contrasted with the “absolutist states” of Iberia, whose despotic rulers purportedly intervened arbitrarily in commercial activities. Recent research by Henriques and Palma (Reference Henriques and Palma2023), however, casts doubt on the start date of the institutional divergence: until the mid-seventeenth century, Spain and Portugal both compare favorably with England in the frequency of their parliamentary meetings, currency debasements, extraordinary taxes, and in their sovereign risk. Reconstruction of Portugal’s national accounts, moreover, reveals a dynamic early modern economy. The period of Portuguese reversal, in both absolute and relative terms, only began in the second half of the 1700s (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019).

In this paper, we show that eighteenth-century Portugal was beset by a resource curse because of gold inflows from Brazil, whose outer provinces were remitting over 70 percent of global output to Lisbon by 1730 in a continued process that would last decades. Treasure imports, mainly private, were a sudden addition to real incomes, which were then spent on domestic products, driving up prices and wages in the non-traded sector, as had previously happened in Spain (Charotti, Palma, and Santos 2022).Footnote 1 This led to an appreciation of the real exchange rate and attracted productive factors from the increasingly uncompetitive traded sector, lowering output and raising costs. Portuguese consumers found imports cheaper and began to substitute these for home goods. The Dutch disease thus manifested itself in relative price movements: traded prices were internationally determined and remained stagnant by comparison with inflation in the non-traded sector. By constructing relative price indices for four Portuguese regions using archival data, we show that such movements did, in fact, occur during and in the wake of the gold shock. We further explore the temporal relationship between persistent real exchange Footnote 2 rate fluctuations and various indicators of economic development—real GDP and wages, the non-agricultural population share, and trade balance statistics—to test for long-term structural consequences. Our price data for the period between 1650 and 1800 shows that a real exchange rate appreciation of about 30 percent occurred during the eighteenth century, leading to a loss of competitiveness in national industry. Following this evidence regarding the economic aspects of the resource curse, we move to an overall assessment of the resource curse. The latter also includes a political component that resulted from the additional revenues due to the gold reducing the rulers’ incentives to negotiate and leading to a complementary process of state capture. We document these events and compute a counterfactual using a synthetic control method. This suggests that the price level in Portugal rose relative to other countries. By 1800, Portugal’s GDP per capita was over 40 percent lower than it would have been if Portugal had not been the first-stage receiver of Brazilian gold.Footnote 3

Our results are related to but contrast with much of the existing literature. As early as 1701, the colonial administrator D. João de Lencastre raised concerns that Brazilian gold would not benefit Portugal in the long run, but instead England or the Netherlands, just as had happened with Spain’s silver (Boxer Reference Boxer1962, p. 42). A decade later, an Italian Jesuit living in Brazil also expressed his opinion that the gold mines were detrimental to the development of Portugal, despite being sparse on details (Antonil Reference Antonil2011, p. 266). In the twentieth century, Vitorino M. Godinho argued that commercial crises related to poorer export-sector performance led to surges of successful industrial policy. In contrast, when colonial booms returned, the former was abandoned (Godinho Reference Godinho1955, pp. 258, 292). Relatedly, Macedo (Reference Macedo1982a, p. 200) argued that once the gold inflows diminished in the last quarter of the eighteenth century, the economy largely recovered. Footnote 4 However, this viewpoint is not supported by the most recent data on structural change and growth: Portugal’s economy never recovered from the industrial decline that occurred during the eighteenth century (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019; Palma Reference Palma2020).

Contrary to views foregrounding the supposed long-run neutrality of money, the resource curse can have persistently negative effects on developing economies.Footnote 5 In the case of eighteenth-century Portugal, the gold inflows encouraged the substitution of foreign imports, and caused a severe contraction of the export sector, diminishing employment across a range of critical industries. These included both manufacturing and agriculture (Fisher Reference Fisher1963; Costa and Reis Reference Costa and Reis2017). When technological progress (or the potential for it) depends on the lagging traded sector—which, given the scalability of newly industrialized textiles, was the situation in early modern European economies—the contraction of these industries slows per capita income growth (Van Wijnbergen Reference Wijnbergen1984). Matsuyama (Reference Matsuyama1992) similarly suggests that the reorientation of activity away from a manufacturing sector characterized by externalities in production could have negative growth effects in a dual-sector open economy. Therefore, the effects of Dutch disease on economic dynamism can be profound and enduring.Footnote 6

In Portugal, a significant real exchange rate appreciation occurred during the first half of the eighteenth century. Footnote 7 The price of non-traded goods in terms of traded goods rose precipitously in all the regions of Portugal after around 1700, exceeding the pre-gold era level by over 30 percent following the 1720s. This coincided with the peak of gold output, which exceeded 140,000 kilograms in the decade 1741–1751 (TePaske Reference TePaske2010). Notably, the price movements coincided with a period of general price inflation and were driven primarily by accelerated increases in the non-traded sector. These developments are as predicted by the standard Dutch disease model, and diminished output of traded goods as imports increased and factors of production flowed into the non-traded sector.

As real exchange rates turned against Portuguese exports, the burgeoning expansion of the late seventeenth century stalled. Urbanization fell from 17.3 to 16.2 percent between 1750 and 1800, while the rural non-agricultural share—representing much of the nation’s handicrafts—remained static at around 29 percent; further declines would continue into the nineteenth century (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019, p. 485). Real GDP and wages stagnated and then declined during the same period, only starting to recover more than a century later. Footnote 8 At a time when urbanization and per capita output were rising across a fast-commercializing Western Europe, Portugal’s decades of outright depression from the 1770s stand out in stark relief.

This paper contributes to literatures in both economics and economic history. Corden and Neary (1982) and Corden (Reference Corden1984) present the basic formulation of Dutch disease theory, but the model is limited by the fact that the distortion ends with the monetary stimulus; in Portugal, GDP per head continued to decline after gold imports had ended. Van Wijnbergen (Reference Wijnbergen1984), Krugman (Reference Krugman1987), Matsuyama (Reference Matsuyama1992), and Sachs and Warner (Reference Sachs and Warner1995) link resource abundance with reduced economic growth to varying degrees through a decline in the size of the traded sector, and Gylfason, Herbertsson, and Zoega (Reference Gylfason, Herbertsson and Zoega1999) explicitly tie real exchange rate appreciation to a contraction of skill-intensive manufacturing. Asea and Lahiri (Reference Asea and Lahiri1999) show that the increased marginal product of unskilled labor slows human capital accumulation by making education costlier. Among others, Forsyth and Nicholas (Reference Forsyth and Nicholas1983) applied the Dutch disease model to early modern Spain, while Stein and Stein (Reference Stein and Stein2000) considered a political channel. Palma (Reference Palma2020) and Charotti, Palma, and Santos (2022) emphasize both channels and review the literature related to early modern Spain. Our resource curse interpretation of the economic and political history of eighteenth-century Portugal suggests a path that largely repeats the earlier story of Spain.Footnote 9

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

It is well known that countries with abundant natural resources often experience negative economic and political consequences. A resource curse has both an economic manifestation (Dutch disease) and a political one (known as the political or institutional resource curse), manifesting itself in reduced checks on executive power, poor governance, and weak rule of law. Footnote 10 In this section, we provide the historical context of Portugal’s experience, including a description of the gold arrivals, and a narrative concerning the evolution of the industrial sector over the eighteenth century. The most striking fact of early modern Portuguese economic history is that real GDP per capita fell by one-third between 1750 and 1800, and it stagnated during the first half of the nineteenth century, just as other parts of Western Europe were industrializing and entering modern economic growth (Table 1). Around 1800, Portugal had endured a century that left it with a barely existent industrial sector and inadequate political institutions. As Figure 1 shows, Portugal saw a decrease in the size of its non-agricultural sector just as each of its European rivals were either flattening (Italy) or experiencing structural transformation out of agriculture. The consequences of the status quo around 1800 would continue to be felt in the future, but they are the result of earlier economic and political developments, as we document in this paper.

Table 1 GDP PER CAPITA OF SELECTED WESTERN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES IN CONSTANT PRICES (“INTERNATIONAL” GEARY-KHAMIS DOLLARS OF 1990)

Sources: Data for England from Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015). This corresponds to Britain from 1700. In the case of Holland, borders correspond to Holland until 1800 and the Netherlands for 1850; a benchmark for 1807 was used for the data prior to 1800 (van Zanden and van Leeuwen Reference van Zanden and van Leeuwen2012, p. 121), and the 1850 level is from Smits, Horlings, and van Zanden (2000). Data for France from Ridolfi and Nuvolari (Reference Ridolfi and Nuvolari2021, p. 419). Germany corresponds to the 1871 borders and the data comes from Pfister (Reference Pfister2022); Spain, from Prados de la Escosura, Álvarez-Nogal, and Santiago-Caballero (Reference Prados de la Escosura, Carlos and Carlos2022). Portuguese data is from Palma and Reis (Reference Palma and Reis2019). “Italy” corresponds to northern and central Italy and comes from Malanima (Reference Malanima2013). Swedish data is from Krantz (Reference Krantz2017) for 1500–1560 and Schön and Krantz (Reference Schön and Krantz2015) for 1560–1850.

Figure 1 SHARES OF POPULATION OUTSIDE AGRICULTURE FOR EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

Sources: Keibek (Reference Keibek2017) for England; Palma and Reis (Reference Palma and Reis2019) for Portugal; Ridolfi and Nuvolari (Reference Ridolfi and Nuvolari2021) for France; Chilosi and Ciccarelli (Reference Chilosi and Ciccarelli2022) for Italy. Figures for Spain derived by back projecting from urban population shares adjusted to net out urban dwellers living on agriculture, using the average of the labor share in 1787 and 1797 as a benchmark, according to the population census for these two years (66.1 percent) (Prados de la Escosura, Álvarez-Nogal, and Santiago-Caballero Reference Prados de la Escosura, Carlos and Carlos2022). We thank Leandro Prados de la Escosura for this suggestion.

The Discovery and Import of Gold from Brazil

Around 1694, alluvial gold was discovered in a province of Portuguese Brazil known today as Minas Gerais. The original explorers were adventurers searching for native slaves and silver, and they sought for a time to keep the finding a secret. By 1697, however, the word was out, and an unprecedented gold rush wave of internal and external migration eventually swept the region (Magalhães Reference Magalhães2005). Gold was found in other surrounding regions of Brazil as well. As many as 50,000 prospectors and their slaves may have inhabited the mining towns as early as 1705 (Boxer Reference Boxer1969, pp. 455–57). Gold hunters arrived en masse from Portugal.Footnote 11 Before long, gold was flowing back to Europe in vast quantities, some in the form of taxes—usually the “royal fifth” (quinto) levied on domestic production—but mostly through remittances by the private contractors who predominated in the mines, which were privately owned. Footnote 12 The quantities produced were extraordinary, peaking at about 14,000 kg per year around 1750. Footnote 13 While local governors strove to regulate exports, smuggling was sometimes successful, especially prior to 1720; powerful merchants in the annual Lisbon fleets hid treasures in barrels, chests, and sugar bags, while informants were discouraged (Boxer, Reference Boxer1969, pp. 459–61). TePaske (Reference TePaske2010), estimating aggregate Brazilian production from 1690 to 1810, suggests that output stood at 40,000 kilograms during each of the first two decades of the eighteenth century, before exploding to 100,000 kilograms in the 1720s and over 140,000 in the 1730s. Of this total, more than 80 percent returned to Portugal (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, p. 204). Three annual fleets shipped an average of 3 billion reis apiece, the proceeds of which were distributed to around 2,300 private individuals (Costa, Rocha, and de Sousa 2013, p. 1148; Costa, Rocha, and Brito 2018).

Most treasure was private. Footnote 14 It generally arrived already minted and about 72 percent was eventually re-exported (de Sousa Reference de Sousa2006, p. 244). The arrivals directly raised incomes considerably in the short term. The gold inflows lasted for around a century, however, and there were net negative effects still during this time frame. After a boom of around four decades in the first half of the eighteenth century, Portugal’s economy stagnated for around two decades, and then began a process of absolute and relative economic decline from the 1770s (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019)—at a time when important gold inflows were still taking place (Costa, Rocha, and de Sousa 2013).

Portugal ran current account deficits (paid for in gold) with all of its major trading partners during the eighteenth century, particularly with England (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016; Fisher Reference Fisher1971, p. 197). Footnote 15 The deficit increased steadily throughout the first half of the eighteenth century, stabilizing at around 4,000 million reis per annum by the 1750s. Portuguese annual imports from England rose from 355,000 pounds in 1699–1702 to 1,300,000 pounds in 1756–60, while exports fell from a peak of 387,000 pounds in 1720 to 257,000 pounds over 1756–60.

The bulk of English goods imported to Portugal consisted of woolen textiles—never falling below 70 percent in any year before 1760, and at one stage reaching 84 percent—most of which were then re-exported to Brazil, where demand for durable goods had exploded with the expansion of mineral wealth. Footnote 16 In 40 of the 60 years between 1700 and 1760, the yearly London rate of exchange was at or below the gold export point of 5/5.75d (Fisher Reference Fisher1963, p. 223). A staggering 90 percent of exported gold went to financing the trade deficit with England and France, regularly departing for Plymouth in packet boats, which carried diplomatic immunity and were thus able to evade prohibitions set on metallic outflows (Francis Reference Francis1966, pp. 216–17). As Figure 2 illustrates, for decades, gold corresponded to 70 percent of the value of Portuguese exports—thus playing a crucial role in balancing the distorted current account. Footnote 17 The peak of gold remittances and the trough of the trade deficit essentially coincide during the early 1750s. By then, all Portuguese factories had failed except for a few highly subsidized cases (Pedreira Reference Pedreira2005, p. 196).

Figure 2 GOLD EXPORTS AS A PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL EXPORTS (INCLUDING GOLD)

Sources: Figures for gold derived from Costa, Rocha, and de Sousa (2013), cited with export figures in Costa, Lains, and Miranda (2016, p. 205).

Portugal’s increasing deficits with England must be seen in the context of the Methuen Treaty of 1703, which exchanged preferential rates on English textiles (23 percent) for a reduction in wine tariffs to one-third below those allotted to France.Footnote 18 While it is tempting to see the agreement as a codification of core-periphery relations between the two countries, establishing the former as a manufacturer and the latter as a primary product exporter, to do so would be anachronistic. Tariffs on English textile imports were not reduced but instead an official restatement of a secret clause in a 1654 peace treaty that guaranteed these same rates, which had not previously been enforced by customs officials. The new article introduced in the Methuen Treaty of December 1703 corresponded to the opening of the English market to Portuguese wines, and the whole treaty always had a military component to it; most immediately, it concerned Portugal’s participation in the Grand Alliance during the War of the Spanish Succession (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, p. 140). The Treaty hence had military as well as economic implications, and it kept political conditions between the two powers stable, such that the effects of gold imports on the balance of trade could unfold according to largely economic factors. The signing of the Methuen Treaty in late 1703 hence mattered, but it was endogenous to the gold inflows that by then were arriving and were expected to continue to arrive in increasing quantities to Portugal (Macedo Reference Macedo1982a, p. 45). Indeed, when gold inflows shrank and trade accounts partially rebalanced from the early 1770s, the agreement was still legally binding (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, p. 200). The Methuen Treaty thus contributed to the de-industrialization of Portugal’s economy, but it was merely a mechanism, not the ultimate cause.

A substantial share of the extracted treasure was retained within Portugal. Costa, Rocha, and Brito (2018, p. 1153) show that the domestic gold stock rose from 1.149 billion reis in 1720 (or 1.4 percent of nominal GDP) to more than 58 billion reis by mid-century (56.4 percent) (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019; Reis Reference Reis2002). The growth rate of the money supply, 2.5 percent per annum, substantially exceeded output growth over the course of the eighteenth century; 80 percent of this total consisted of coins, most of which were private and many of which were invested in land—a fundamental factor in the non-traded sector (Costa, Rocha, and Brito 2018, p. 1153). Growing demand for land led the Pombal administration, once the gold inflows began to shrink, to eventually restrict property transfers to the Church and suppress entailments to improve market liquidity, measures which, though unsuccessful, reflect the rising value of a static resource. In the southern Alentejo region, rising meat prices—a non-traded good—led to wholesale conversion to husbandry from cereal cultivation, which remained comparatively inefficient (yield ratios for wheat and rye were below 1:4). Overall agricultural production, which had risen steadily since 1660 (at .72 percent per annum according to one estimate), declined from 1750 until the Napoleonic Wars. Olive oil and wine exports both flourished, but these were products with no ready substitutes, and their producers had gained access to foreign consumers through diplomatic means, including the 1703 Methuen Treaty (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, pp. 172–73). These sectors did little to arrest the steady decline of Portuguese shipments abroad.

As expected, real wages rose during the gold boom period. Footnote 19 Data is scarce on manufactures, but even with state industrial policy intervention during the second half of the eighteenth century, industrial development was sluggish at best. By 1769, only four textile factories were operating in the entirety of Portugal, and outside the royal factories, the scale of production remained desperately small (Pedreira Reference Pedreira1994, p. 59). Even the larger, state-run institutions were, in fact, glorified systems of organizing and subcontracting to existing networks of cottage production. Faced with daunting initial investment costs and insufficient capital, the only sizeable enterprises to be established were erected behind heavy tariffs and import bans. Pombal’s “industrial policy” did not change the previous structure of production; of 200 “program” facilities reported in 1777, the majority were small-scale workshops (Macedo Reference Macedo1982a, pp. 155–60). Indeed, the proliferation starting after 1777 (jumping from 55 to 235 factories) was associated with a liberalization of the import-licensing system to allow minor firms to set up. Of the 180 applications for licenses between 1757 and 1832, 114 (63 percent) were by foreigners, bespeaking the absence of domestic industrial entrepreneurship and capital (Pedreira Reference Pedreira1994, p. 59). The small scale of these undertakings, many of which were located in the interior of the country where transport costs shielded them from international competition, slowed the adoption of mechanized technologies, a further contributing factor delaying the onset of the Industrial Revolution.Footnote 20

Portuguese Industry Prior to 1700

Assessing the true costs of Portugal’s contraction requires a plausible counterfactual for the evolution of the eighteenth-century economy in the absence of the discovery of gold in Brazil. The starting point for such a scenario is the expansion of the Portuguese economy in the second half of the seventeenth century, following the end of the Iberian Union with the restoration of a Portuguese dynasty in 1640 and the end of hostilities in 1668. At this stage, Portugal was on the cusp of a strong advance in per capita income and structural transformation away from agriculture. From 1650 to 1700, the percentage of the population employed in agriculture shrank from 63.7 percent to 58.9 percent, while the rural non-agricultural share rose from 23.9 percent to 28.6 percent. Per capita incomes grew once hostilities ended, from around 900 “international” G-K dollars of 1990 in the 1640–1660s to more than more than 1,200 by the early 1690s (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019, pp. 485, 497).

Portugal had a venerable tradition in rural manufacturing.Footnote 21 By the late seventeenth century the country had a growing industrial sector that included clusters of textile, soap, iron, glass, and silk manufacturing, among others (Macedo Reference Macedo1982a, pp. 25, 28). By 1680, Portugal’s textile industry not only supplied the needs of Portugal and its colonies, but also exported valuable textiles to Castile (Pedreira Reference Pedreira1994, p. 26, 2005). Industrialization progressed steadily during the 1680s (Dias Reference Dias1954). A successful industrialization effort, promoted by Luís de Menezes, the Count of Ericeira, was in place for more than a decade, having started shortly after the end of hostilities with Spain in the late 1660s and being abandoned only after 1700 (Macedo Reference Macedo1982a, pp. 25, 29). Footnote 22 The industrialization effort had an associated vertical integration at the retail level and was located in many of the same regions that industrialized on a larger scale more than two centuries later (Macedo Reference Macedo1982a, p. 32). In addition to an import-substitution policy, prior to 1700, there was also much investment in increasing the efficiency of the manufacturing process, including through the construction of new factories in Covilhã, Manteigas, Estremoz, Vila Melo, Fundão, and Lisbon—with other factories having been planned, but never been constructed, in Porto and Portalegre (Meneses Reference Meneses2001; Macedo Reference Macedo1982a, p. 36).Footnote 23

Portugal had the advantage of Brazil as both an export market and supplier of agricultural raw materials and other inputs, as well as tropical products for re-export (including sugar).Footnote 24 Until the 1690s, the political will existed to make Portugal a mercantilist exporting power. The industrial development of the last three decades of the seventeenth century was simultaneous with an industrial policy based on import substitution. Footnote 25 This was implemented through a sequence of laws between 1672 and 1698. They were known as leis pragmaticas and supported by the writings of individuals such as Duarte Ribeiro de Macedo, who from the 1670s strongly advocated for industrialization, influenced by Colbertism and the writings of English mercantilists. Ericeira became a key politician who from 1675 targeted woolens, silks, glass, and iron-working, granting large production units monopoly status as “royal factories” to reap the potential gains of concentration and protection. Footnote 26 In 1677, Covilhã was the site of a new public-private partnership for textile production. A plant was established on the bank of a stream, weavers were contracted, and English technicians were brought in. Footnote 27 Rural putting-out handled the spinning, while the dyeing and carding occurred in-house. Three years in, 17 looms were operated by 23 weavers apiece, and the contractors employed a total of 415 people. The success of the enterprise led to expansion into the neighboring town of Manteigas and plans for its replication in Estremoz. Footnote 28 From the 1770s, the Crown encouraged the development of the silk industry, with thousands of mulberry trees planted in different areas of the country (Lourenço, Reference Lourenço2007, p. 308). Silk factories opened in Lisbon and elsewhere. There were also important advances in metallurgy, particularly in nail production (Hanson Reference Hanson1981). Vertical integration with respect to iron production was encouraged, even after the death of Ericeira (Hanson Reference Hanson1981).

By the late seventeenth century, then, Portugal had the rudiments of a successful industrial take-off. This fact was noticed by international observers, such as the French Ambassador in Portugal who commented on the successful industrialization effort that was happening (Lourenço Reference Lourenço2007, p. 306). Several “rural industrial districts” built on sophisticated putting-out networks existed, there was a large, mercantile capital city stimulating demand for manufactures, and Brazil provided a potentially enormous export market and supplier of raw materials. By 1680, Portugal’s textile industry was, in fact, not only supplying the needs of the internal market including Brazil but it was also exporting to Castile. Portugal never became an industrial, exporting power at this time—but if the 1670s–1690s trends had continued, this could have happened over the eighteenth century. Instead, in the first half of the eighteenth century Portugal’s industry lost its competitiveness and experienced serious difficulties (Pedreira Reference Pedreira2005, p. 194). The sources of such difficulties have been debated, with some claiming them to be related to the indiscipline of its workers or the actions of the Inquisition, while others claiming it to be related to the import of the gold coins (Pedreira Reference Pedreira2005, p. 194). We provide evidence for the latter as the fundamental cause. In its absence, Portugal could have used import-substitution on the motherland to combine proto-industrial networks with urban manufacturing, importing inputs and exporting manufactures to and from its privileged market of Brazil. Footnote 29 As it was, however, agglomeration economies with long-term consequences did not occur, and Portugal’s backward industrial structure persisted into the nineteenth century and beyond (Pedreira Reference Pedreira2005, pp. 205–06). Additionally, the deteriorating quality of political institutions had negative consequences for human capital accumulation, which we will explain later. Portugal would only industrialize and enter a process of modern economic growth from the mid-twentieth century—extraordinarily late by Western European standards.

DATA AND RESULTS

In this section, we provide details about our data construction, methodology, and empirical results. Testing for Dutch disease requires detailed information on the prices of a range of traded and non-traded goods, so as to establish whether an appreciation in the real exchange rate occurred. We utilize data from the Price, Wages, and Rents in Portugal 1310–1900 (henceforth PWR) project, which collects long-run data of the aforementioned variables from primary sources available in archives in Portugal. Footnote 30 The database relies on a variety of primary record sources, including hospitals, charitable institutions (Misericórdias), convents and monasteries, royal palaces, municipal bodies, and the University of Coimbra. The price indices to be discussed later are constructed by us from numbers converted from their original values in geographically varying Portuguese measures to a metric standard. Footnote 31 Our selected time ranges from 1650 to 1825. We construct indexes as follows:

where q k corresponds to the quantity purchased of good k, p k,t is the nominal price of good k at time t in monetary units (reis) per metric units, N is the number of goods 1,2,…,N, and i is an indicator concerning whether the good is traded (t) or non-traded (nt).

To build the traded and non-traded indices, we first had to choose a relevant set of goods. We used the set of goods and weights employed by Allen (Reference Allen2001), in his respectability consumption basket, as modified for Portugal by Palma and Reis (Reference Palma and Reis2019). We then divided these goods into two categories, displayed in Table 2: traded and non-traded. No early modern good was fully traded, except in rare cases, but a range of products have been shown to have been either competitive enough in foreign markets (such as wine) or in domestic port cities (such as wheat). Costa, Lains, and Miranda (2016) show that nearly 80 percent of all imports were manufactures as of 1685, and that most of the remainder consisted of cereals, dairy products, and fish. The same source suggests that 914 million reis worth of wine and olive oil combined were exported, along with smaller but still significant quantities of salt. With this in mind, we selected wheat (substituting for maize, as dictated by historical consumption patterns and discussed later), olive oil, wine, linen, and candles as traded goods, and meat, hens, eggs, soap, and charcoal as non-traded. Live animals were difficult to move across national borders, and no evidence from the trade accounts suggested that animal products—beyond salted cod—were moved in significant quantities. Eggs and soap Footnote 32 were too fragile to be moved, while neither charcoal nor firewood appear in the lists of traded goods from Fisher (Reference Fisher1971) and Costa, Lains, and Miranda (2016), presumably because they were too heavy relative to their value.Footnote 33

Table 2 TRADED AND NON-TRADED CATEGORIES AND WEIGHTS

Sources: Quantities derived from Palma and Reis (Reference Palma and Reis2019), in turn based on the weighting scheme described in Allen (Reference Allen2001), with appropriate adaptations for Portugal.

Finally, we combine the traded and non-traded baskets into separate indices by using the Laspeyres method, following Allen (Reference Allen2001).Footnote 34 To smooth out volatile premodern commodity prices and examine long-term trends, we convert the indices into 11-year moving averages. Even so, spikes in the prices of heavily weighted goods remain visible in the overall picture. We follow Palma and Reis (Reference Palma and Reis2019) in increasing the fraction of maize in the grain content of flour as wheat becomes more expensive, reflecting production shares derived from tithes. Footnote 35 Finally, we construct a whole Portugal series combining the baskets from the four regions, with the traded and non-traded figures consisting of population-weighted averages of the values for each location. We depict the real exchange rate appreciation as an increase in the price of non-traded relative to traded goods.

Empirical Results

Figure 3 plots the ratio between the indexed prices of the traded and non-traded baskets from 1650 to 1825 for the entire country of Portugal. The vertical black line stands at 1694, coincident with the approximate start of gold inflows from Brazil. Several distinct phases are evident: first, a declining real exchange rate during the half-century prior to 1690; second, a steep appreciation (by over 30 percent) from around 1700 until 1720; third, a high plateau peaking after 1750; and fourth, a gradual but muted recovery after 1775. Significantly, the path of gold production in Portuguese Brazil (shown by the dashed gray line) is proportionate to the real exchange rate dynamics. The peak of Figure 3 follows soon after the peak year of output, in which more than 14,000 kilograms were extracted.

Figure 3 RATIO OF NON-TRADED TO TRADED PRICE INDICES FOR PORTUGAL, 1650–1820

Notes: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal. The price index shown here corresponds to an 11-year moving average.

Sources: Price data from PWR. Gold production in Portuguese Brazil from TePaske (Reference TePaske2010).

Two trends stand out: a short, sharp appreciation followed by persistently expensive non-traded goods, which even by 1800—as gold imports dwindled—remained 20 percent above traded prices relative to 1694 levels. Close examination reveals that the recovery is largely due to the rising price of wheat during the last half of the eighteenth century. Given the high weight placed on cereal grains, despite the partial maize substitution that occurred, the movement of wheat prices led to an increase in the overall price level. However, this figure tends to overstate the extent to which the traded index rose; the price of wheat increased due to the simultaneous growth of population after 1730 and stagnation of agricultural output (concomitant with the transfer of farmland to husbandry discussed previously). Gradually substituting maize for wheat as the latter grew increasingly expensive—as is both historically accurate and theoretically plausible—mutes this distortion. Portugal’s major exports, wine and olive oil, saw essentially flat nominal prices throughout the eighteenth century. Linens—for which English textiles could be substituted—followed a similar pattern, only appreciating (as most goods did) at the time of the Napoleonic Wars. On the non-traded side, beef, pork, eggs, hens, and charcoal all rose sharply in price in the first decade of the eighteenth century, coincident with the arrival of gold imports.

The slow recovery of the real exchange rate during the second half of the eighteenth century points to a persistent effect of continuous gold imports and suggests that the Portuguese economy was slow to adjust to this shock. Elevated non-traded prices are a strong inducement for an influx of productive factors from import-competitive industries, especially as wage and price inflation squeezed profits in the traded sector. This is broadly consistent with the pattern of increasing trade deficits prior to 1750 and the subsequent collapse in product and real wages. Given the extent to which the rising price of wheat drives the recovery of the traded index, imputing the shift to any historical break is hazardous; yet the partial recovery of Portugal’s competitive position coincides with the diminution of the country’s trade deficit. It remains unclear to what extent this was simply related to lower gold inflows or Pombal’s aggressive import-substitution program. In any event, the fact that non-traded industries remained expensive into the nineteenth century aligns well with the observed trends of Portugal’s economy: by 1850, all early modern per capita income gains were lost, and income per capita was at a level similar to that of 1527 (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019).

Figure 4 shows the real exchange rate for Lisbon over the same period. Footnote 36 Unsurprisingly, the trends correspond closely with the national version—weighting by population gives much predominance to the capital and its hinterland. Note that the population of the city of Lisbon in fact even after the 1755 earthquake remained nearly four times that of Porto, the next-largest city. Footnote 37 This is fortunate, as the price data for Lisbon is the most complete and least volatile. The Lisbon figure undergoes several distinct phase changes—a falling exchange rate before 1694, a dramatic appreciation after 1710 (by 30–40 percent), and a recovery after 1750. This should be expected of the nation’s commercial hub: Lisbon, as the principal site of gold offloading and foreign trade, would have most completely absorbed the monetary shock and had prices that more closely reflected “exogenous” world market values.

Figure 4 RATIO OF NON-TRADED TO TRADED PRICE INDICES FOR LISBON, 1650–1820

Note: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal.

Sources: Price data from PWR. Gold production in Portuguese Brazil from TePaske (Reference TePaske2010).

An Augmented Synthetic Control Approach

To provide empirical evidence for this counterfactual conjecture and establish the viability of the Portuguese economy in the absence of gold, we use the augmented synthetic control method (Ben-Michael, Feller, and Rothstein Reference Ben-Michael, Feller and Rothstein2021). This allows for the construction of a counterfactual, built from a weighted average of control units that match Portugal’s pre-treatment outcomes. The estimated impact of the gold is then calculated as the difference in post-treatment outcomes between Portugal and its synthetic doppelganger. In so doing, we show that Portugal’s price level and GDP per capita diverged sharply from its neighbors during the period of the shock and that, more consequentially, this trajectory was inferior to that which would have occurred in its absence.

The synthetic control method employs a two-step approach to comparing a treated unit with a donor pool, from which components are grafted to create a plausible counterfactual. First, the treated unit is compared with the donor pool in a pretreatment period (before 1694 in our case) in order to observe which combination of units from the donor pool best replicates the behavior of the treated unit. In our case, Portugal is compared with other European countries that are used to construct a counterfactual for the post-treatment period. The procedure is designed to ensure that the outcome variables imitate both the levels and the trend of the outcome before treatment occurs. Second, after the treatment (the influx of Brazilian gold) has taken place, we observe how the behavior of the treated unit differs from that of the donor pool. The behavior of the donor pool in the post-treatment period is understood as the counterfactual of how the treated unit would have behaved in the absence of the event. Our counterfactual does not correspond to a situation in which no gold existed in Brazil, but instead to one in which Portugal was a second-stage receiver of the gold windfall. This is because the observational data for donor countries corresponds to the historical scenario in which second-stage receivers potentially benefited from the gold (Palma Reference Palma2018, Reference Palma2020; Chen, Palma, and Ward Reference Chen, Palma and Ward2022).

This procedure requires an appropriate donor pool to construct an optimal combination of weights chosen to minimize the pre-shock differences between Portugal and a synthetic counterfactual. In our analysis, this is built using long time series from a donor pool formed by several Western European countries for which such data exist: England/Britain (Broadberry et al. Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015), Italy (Malanima Reference Malanima2002, Reference Malanima2011), Germany (Pfister Reference Pfister2022), France (Ridolfi and Nuvolari Reference Ridolfi and Nuvolari2021), Spain (Prados de la Escosura, Álvarez-Nogal, and Santiago-Caballero Reference Prados de la Escosura, Carlos and Carlos2022), and Holland (van Zanden and van Leeuwen Reference van Zanden and van Leeuwen2012). Footnote 38 By design, causal inference using this method is valid in settings where an excellent fit on pre-treatment outcomes is possible (Abadie, Diamond, and Hainmueller Reference Abadie, Diamond and Hainmueller2015); when this is infeasible, the Synthetic Control Method (SCM) approach must be modified to adjust for pre-treatment fit. This leads us to the Augmented Synthetic Control Method (ASCM) on which we rely here.

A Counterfactual Portugal

We now report the results of our synthetic control analysis. We follow Ben-Michael Feller, and Rothstein (Reference Ben-Michael, Feller and Rothstein2021) and use the ASCM, which controls pre-treatment fit while minimizing extrapolation, to estimate the long-run impact of Brazilian gold on Portuguese economic development. Formally, we consider a panel data setting with i = 1,…,N units observed for t = 1,…,T time periods. Let W i = 1 be an indicator that the unit i received the treatment at time T 0 < T, and W i = 0 means that the unit i never received the treatment. To simplify the notation, we define the pre-treatment period as T 0 = 1,….,T 0, and the post-treatment period as T = T 0 + 1,…,T. Additionally, we follow the convention that i = 1 is the unit that receives the treatment. Therefore, the observed outcomes of interest are:

(1)

The treatment effect is Y 1T (1) − Y 1T (0). Following Ben-Michael, Feller, and Rothstein (Reference Ben-Michael, Feller and Rothstein2021), we define the ridge-augmented SCM estimator as , where the weights solve:

(2)

where γ is the vector of weights being optimized, is the vector of SCM weights, and λ ridge is the hyperparameter that determines the amount of extrapolation (with the level of imbalance). The second term in Equation (2) is introduced in ASCM equations to penalize deviations from the SCM weights. Footnote 39 We follow the cross-validation approach proposed by Ben-Michael, Feller, and Rothstein (Reference Ben-Michael, Feller and Rothstein2021) and the “one-standard-error” rule (Hastie, Tibshirani, and Friedman Reference Hastie, Tibshirani and Friedman2009) to select λ ridge . We show the resulting weights in the Online Appendix (Table B.3).

In Figure 5, the price level is shown to increase significantly above the synthetic counterfactual immediately in the decades following the chosen treatment date of 1694, concurrent with the growing influx of gold imports. In turn, Figure 6 shows a dramatic divergence between the synthetic and actual GDP measures for Portugal during the second half of the eighteenth century. Footnote 40 GDP declined in absolute terms during much of the second half of the century and ended up over 200 percent lower than the counterfactual path in 1800. Finally, Figure 7 shows the trajectories of the synthetic counterfactual and actual GDP per capita series for Portugal for the treatment, pre-treatment, and post-treatment periods. As predicted, the two corresponded closely prior to the gold shock. During the treatment period, however, distinct divergences appear in the actual and counterfactual outcomes. Following a brief dip after 1700, the historical series booms during the early years of the gold shock, exceeding the actual series around 1750. From this peak, per capita income tumbled sharply, falling well below the simulated trend line by the end of the century.

Figure 5 SYNTHETIC CONTROL RESULTS FOR PORTUGUESE CPI, 1640–1800

Notes: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal. As a robustness check, in Online Appendix Figure B.21 we show the same figure using an unweighted mean, rather than the synthetic counterfactual, and demonstrate that the result is largely unaffected.

Source: See Table 1.

Figure 6 SYNTHETIC CONTROL RESULTS FOR PORTUGUESE GDP, 1640–1800

Notes: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal. As a robustness check, in Online Appendix Figure B.22 we show the same figure using an unweighted mean, rather than the synthetic counterfactual, and demonstrate that the result is largely unaffected.

Source: See Table 1.

Figure 7 SYNTHETIC CONTROL RESULTS FOR PORTUGUESE GDP PER CAPITA, 1640–1800

Notes: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal. As a robustness check, in Online Appendix Figure B.23 we show the same figure using an unweighted mean, rather than the synthetic counterfactual, and demonstrate that the result is largely unaffected.

Source: See Table 1.

Such patterns precisely fit expectations for an economy beset by a resource curse. During the initial decades of the gold inflows, the economy grew faster than the counterfactual, bolstered by rising real wages due to the influx of imported gold. From the mid-century, however, the accumulated structural weaknesses began to manifest, and stagnation from the mid-1750s was soon followed by outright decline from the 1770s (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019). By 1800, GDP per capita was over 40 percent below the counterfactual, as previously mentioned: with the difference between the two series being both economically large and statistically significant.Footnote 41

THE GOLDEN ORIGINS OF PORTUGAL’S DIVERGENCE

The movements exhibited in relative prices and the real exchange rate align with predictions from the Dutch disease theory. In turn, the worsening political environment during the eighteenth century is consistent with an institutional resource curse. It remains to connect these factors more closely with Portugal’s observed economic decline and divergence from Western Europe. The causes of the ailment—whose symptoms included trade deficits and stagnating output—fall into proximate and ultimate categories. The former comprises real exchange rate appreciation, industrial decline, and institutional deterioration; these were driven by colonial gold inflows through a resource curse mechanism. While real exchange rate appreciation, increasing trade deficits, and political challenges are characteristic results of a resource curse, further work will be needed to understand the effects of the gold boom on Portuguese economic performance.

Annual output data are unavailable for most individual industries except agriculture, so a variety of substitute measures must be employed, in particular, to differentiate between the direct consequences of gold via its effect on the economy and its indirect effect via a political resource curse that negatively affects institutions. Footnote 42 Notice however, that the latter effect is not independent of the former: the expansion of the non-tradables sector (e.g., landed and Church-related interests) led to the formation of powerful lobbies as had happened earlier in Spain (Charotti, Palma, and Santos 2022). In Portugal, during the first half of the eighteenth century, King João V (r. 1706–1750) spent a significant proportion of the tax revenues generated by the Brazil windfall on frivolous expenses, including the construction of the huge Palace-Convent of Mafra and an expensive and ostentatious embassy to Pope Clement XI. During this time, there was limited interest in promoting domestic manufacturing, with political priorities focused on maximizing revenues related to gold extraction in Brazil (Pedreira Reference Pedreira1994, pp. 41–42, 2005).

As discussed earlier, between 1720 and 1750, the Portuguese trade deficit rose from 2 billion reis (2.4 percent of nominal GDP) to more than 4 billion (3.9 percent), reaching nearly 6 billion (6.1 percent) in 1756 in the wake of the Lisbon earthquake. Footnote 43 The foreign accounts remained in the negative until the last decade of the eighteenth century, notwithstanding the efforts of Pombal and his successors after 1777 to boost domestic industry and prohibit imports. In any event, Costa, Lains, and Miranda (2016, p. 197) suggest that the restoration of the trade balance was the result of falling domestic consumption, given that exports did not substantially increase. This is also consistent with the evidence of Palma and Reis (Reference Palma and Reis2019) regarding falling real incomes in the last decades of the eighteenth century, well before the Napoleonic invasion in 1807. Footnote 44 Even the suppression of Brazilian manufacturing by a decree of 5 January 1785, and Pombal’s earlier efforts to exclude English “interlopers” from the colonial trade through the assignment of monopoly rights failed to lift exports considerably, and if their value rose at the end of the century, this was at least partly the result of a pan-European wave of price inflation. So long as the golden tide flowed into Lisbon, Portugal was doomed to involution.Footnote 45

Did individual traded and non-traded industries fit the general pattern? Not much reliable data exists on manufacturing, but what limited figures can be adduced are not suggestive of general expansion. In 1769, only 15 factories existed across the country at large; just four of these produced textiles, the growth sector of the British Industrial Revolution (Pedreira Reference Pedreira1994, p. 59). Metallurgy, silk throwing, and dyeing were all neglected, while cotton, woolens, and linen each received only one new venture. Given that between 1736 and 1740 Portugal was purchasing half of the English textile industry’s exports (Fisher Reference Fisher1971, p. 144), demand for manufactured goods clearly outstripped the supply response of domestic industry. There was no push, as in England, toward modernization and mechanization; rather, the traditional putting-out system that had persisted since the sixteenth century was nearly universal. Larger-scale operations—either state-run or state-sponsored—merely subcontracted tasks to peasant production networks. Only by the turn of the century, once gold imports had nearly ceased, does any evidence appear of output and exports marginally increasing. However, the picture was not optimistic, given the low base from which industry restarted, and the fact that Brazil—subjected to a colonial monopoly until 1808—was the primary recipient of Portugal’s manufactures. The share of population outside agriculture, which had risen quickly until 1750, then fell from 46.5 percent in 1750 to 33.1 percent a century later (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019). Footnote 46 The technical stagnation noted previously, therefore, would be a predictable consequence of this contraction. While Lisbon and Porto did experience strong urban growth during the eighteenth century, they were “consumption cities” dependent on the provision of non-traded services. Gollin, Jedwab, and Vollrath (Reference Gollin, Jedwab and Vollrath2016) find that consumption cities, by contrast with manufacturing-based “production cities,” tend to proliferate in countries with high levels of natural resource exports. Lisbon, home to the Crown and Court, proved a particularly voracious consumer of goods funded by gold imports. While aggregate demand increased, Lisbon’s status as a hub for foreign trade ensured that much of this was siphoned off into purchases of foreign manufactures (Fisher Reference Fisher1963).

Viticulture is a potential confounding factor. Both wine and olive oil saw increased production, with the former doubling in cultivated areas during the 1700s. Over 70 percent of wine output was exported to England, while olive oil was also traded, especially with Brazil. The foreign demand for these products boosted wine prices throughout the latter half of the eighteenth century. Yet the nature of the industry should give the skeptic pause. First, port wine had no close international substitutes; beer was not treated as such, as evidenced by the behavior of British consumers, while the Methuen Treaty undercut French competition. Thus, even if costs increased and opportunities arose to switch capital and labor into the non-traded sector, wine producers were able to compensate with higher prices. Diplomacy protected the winemaker. Furthermore, the growth of a traded subsector is consistent with Dutch disease. According to the Corden-Neary decomposed “Paradox Model” (see Online Appendix A), the most capital-intensive lagging industries might raise production at the expense of competing trades. Wine was surprisingly capital-intensive, and small farmers were unable to muster the investment necessary to compete with the nobility and urban elites who dominated the sector. Thus, the decrease in available labor might well have tended to increase the output of viticulture, and the evidence suggests that both cereal and wasteland were extensively converted for this purpose.

Cereal production, meanwhile, suffered an unambiguous decrease in output during the second half of the eighteenth century (Reis Reference Reis2017). Total factor productivity fell over this period, and yields remained both low and stagnant by European standards (averaging 1:4, and never exceeding 1:7). Though the introduction of maize proved increasingly successful, Portugal continued to import increasing amounts of grain, peaking at 151.6 tons worth (as discussed earlier) by 1800. Lisbon’s foreign consumption rose from an already-high 55 percent in 1729 to a colossal 72 percent by 1778 (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, p. 183). Though this figure was smaller for the country at large (5.5 to 7 percent), it was still considerably more than England’s 3 percent, and was impressive in an age of debilitating overland transport costs. Indeed, 5 to 12 percent of Britain’s rising exports to Portugal were consisted of wheat throughout the period (Fisher Reference Fisher1963, p. 222). Due to low productivity and profits, vast tracts of land were switched over to pastoral husbandry, with grain production restricted to poor soils (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, p. 180). Since the raising of cattle and sheep is more capital-intensive, this outcome should be expected within a Dutch disease model. Furthermore, the contraction of the sector would have hindered productivity advances, and the changes in techniques that revolutionized agriculture in eighteenth-century England were absent in contemporary Portugal.

Resource Curse: Economic and Political Consequences

Gold directly augmented incomes—of some people, and in the short run. Increasing gold production in Brazil enriched Portuguese nationals in the colonies, who either remitted their funds home or exchanged them directly for the durable goods arriving on the thrice-annual treasure fleets. Footnote 47 Newly expanded incomes would necessarily increase demand in the non-traded sector, causing a real appreciation and a consequent withdrawal of resources from the lagging sector through the spending effect. Footnote 48 A smaller though still significant contraction might follow from the emigration of hundreds of thousands of Portuguese prospectors and other individuals working on their supply lines, which would constitute a resource movement effect. With the collapse of the traded export sector and the increased purchasing power of the currency, exports would decline and imports surge, increasing the trade deficit. Gold re-exportation would then be required to pay the outstanding balances, as the proceeds of domestic industry no longer earn foreign exchange.

In the long run, the decades-long influx of gold would have continued to compress the traded sector. Skill-based productivity advances, which depended on industry and cereal agriculture, were persistently stifled, removing the principal driver of expansion. After an initial boom, therefore, GDP growth rates slowed, and eventually reversed, with critical sectors of the economy being replaced by imports and with the practical consequences of worsening political institutions. Though wine prices and exports apparently flourished, this can be reconciled with the “decomposed” traded-sector model discussed in Online Appendix A, with land as an additional mobile factor. This aligns with the general pattern of farms being transferred to relatively land- and capital-intensive industries, especially viticulture and husbandry, throughout the course of the eighteenth century. Costa and Reis (Reference Costa and Reis2017) estimate that the 1750–1800 period was the only extended span in Portuguese history in which there was a trade deficit in the agricultural sector. The growing success of English textiles in both the home and Brazilian markets, meanwhile, indicates that domestic production was increasingly not competitive.

As noted in the second section, Portugal’s increased efforts to sustainably boost industrial production failed. Yet, the implementation of import-substitution policies during the second half of the eighteenth century hints at contemporary recognition by Pombal that gold imports (and re-exportation) led to economic involution. Some writers of the period were in fact at least vaguely aware of the negative consequences of gold imports (Antonil Reference Antonil2011; da Silva Reference da Silva2013). Footnote 49 The tariffs, bans, and state entrepreneurship of the Pombal era were coupled with the capture and protection of the Brazilian market on behalf of domestic merchants. In the second half of the century, manufacturing in the colony was banned outright, and, as mentioned, efforts were made to reduce the influence of “interloper” English shippers and producers by granting monopoly rights to chartered companies. The Company of Grão-Pará and Maranhão exploited state credit to establish primary product plantations in cacao, rice, coffee, and cotton, for which they exchanged manufactured exports, which rose to 43.1 percent of all goods sent to the colony by 1800 (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, pp. 206–08). There is no basis for attributing Portugal’s economic ineptitude to a historically poor representation of merchant interests due to comparatively backward political institutions going back to 1500 or earlier (Henriques and Palma Reference Henriques and Palma2023). But it is nonetheless true that the merchant push of the Pombal era was state-led and associated with rent-seeking, crony capitalism, and state capture (Madureira Reference Madureira1997; Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, pp. 215–16). Accordingly, negative structural transformation occurred despite concerted state efforts to boost industry at the expense of Brazil. Overall, the resource curse meant that Portugal’s industry not only lost competitiveness but also missed out on the expansion opportunities that, in the absence of Brazilian gold, would have occurred in the eighteenth century and likely continued via agglomeration and other spillover effects (e.g., related to human capital) into the future.

In addition to the direct economic consequences of de-industrialization and missed agglomeration opportunities, Portugal also suffered a political resource curse due to Brazil’s gold. Footnote 50 As late as the second half of the seventeenth century, Portugal’s political institutions, namely courts and parliaments (Cortes), had limited the power of the ruler (Henriques and Palma Reference Henriques and Palma2023). The additional revenues of the Crown from the Brazilian gold windfall and the military protection guaranteed by the Methuen Treaty of 1703, which was itself a result of this, meant that rulers no longer needed to negotiate, and parliaments stopped meeting altogether, leading to reduced executive constraints and a lack of checks and balances.Footnote 51

Previously active in providing checks and balances against executive power, the Cortes never met during the entire eighteenth century. Power accordingly became absolutist, with consequences that peaked during the rule of Sebastião José de Carvalho e Melo (1699–1782), who became Count of Oeiras in 1759 and Marquis of Pombal in 1770. He was the de facto ruler from around 1755 to the death of King José I in 1777. Perhaps most disastrously, Pombal’s educational reforms in association with the expulsion of the Jesuits, who opposed his absolutism, drastically reduced the number of students, and the industrialization effort he promoted was ultimately unsuccessful (Madureira Reference Madureira1997; Macedo Reference Macedo1982a; Pedreira Reference Pedreira2005, pp. 205–06, Romeiras and Leitão Reference Romeiras and Leitão2022). Pombal was responsible for large numbers of political prisoners and for instrumentalizing the Inquisition to pursue his political goals, such as by placing his brother at its head. Footnote 52 He also centralized censorship in his hands (Real Mesa Censória). Footnote 53 His rule was characterized by organized state predation and capture, putting an extractive system in place that continued after his fall in 1777.Footnote 54

Pombal’s unchecked policies were disastrous for human capital formation. There were around 20,000 students in pre-university education until 1759, a figure that Pombal’s reforms from 1759 reduced sharply (Leitão Reference Leitão2007, p. 88). Footnote 55 The same absolute number of pre-university students was only reached again in the 1930s, when the overall population was considerably larger (Romeiras Reference Romeiras2019; Leitão and Romeiras Reference Leitão and Romeiras2015; Palma, Reis, and Zhang Reference Palma, Reis and Zhang2020). Portugal still had a numeracy rate close to the most advanced countries in Europe during the first half of the eighteenth century, but this comparative situation would change drastically in the second half of the eighteenth century (Stolz, Baten, and Reis 2013, pp. 562–64). By 1773, less than a third of the existing primary schools had a teacher (Fernandes Reference Fernandes2006, p. 608). By 1800, literacy rates in Portugal—measured by the percentage of adults who could sign their names—were well behind other parts of Western Europe (Reis Reference Reis2005, p. 202).Footnote 56 The fact that it was the nature of the existing political institutions and not the Catholic religion, which by itself prevented industrialization is suggested by the fact that the second European country to industrialize and enter modern economic growth was Belgium. Footnote 57 The lack of explanatory power of the Catholic religion is also reflected in the absence of observable differences with respect to other variables. For example, there is no evidence of different social norms at the family level, meaning that women were more discriminated against in Southwestern Europe than in Northwestern Europe—a factor that could have led to different fertility practices causing low human capital accumulation and other inferior development outcomes (Palma, Reis, and Rodrigues Reference Palma, Reis and Rodrigues2023). Finally, recent research has shown that Portugal had a high level of state capacity, even when compared with other Western European polities (Costa, Henriques, and Palma Reference Costa, Henriques and Palma2024); hence, its problem lies elsewhere.

CONCLUSION

The decline of Portugal was due to the structural effects of massive gold imports from Brazil, which peaked around the 1740s. In this paper, we have focused on this resource curse. It had an economic aspect (the de-industrialization of the economy) and a complementary political resource curse operating through channels such as additional royal revenues. On the economic front, increasing imports of gold coincided with a strong appreciation of the real exchange rate, which only began to recover with the decline of remittances during the 1770s. Price data obtained from archival sources shows a sharp appreciation of the real exchange rate consistent with the onset of Dutch disease and the loss of competitiveness of the national industry. The prices of traded goods remained for the most part stagnant, except for wheat, whose price alone among grains tended upward during long spells of the eighteenth century. Imports rose throughout the first half of the eighteenth century, with gold remittances and the deficit peaking simultaneously, while exports remained stagnant or declined outright, despite deliberate efforts at import substitution. In sum, there was a sharp rise in the prices of the non-traded sector—chiefly primary products—leading to withdrawn resources from the traded sector, and hence reduced output and employment in manufacturing and grain agriculture. While the economy boomed in the short run, the longer-term effects of the gold shock were negative—contractions in industry and cereal production slowed the accumulation of technical progress, causing stagnant growth in subsequent years. Income growth was permanently reduced. Over the second half of the eighteenth century, the country de-industrialized, and the percentage of the population working outside of agriculture declined from around 46 percent in 1750 to only 33 percent a year later.

In proffering the resource curse as a cause of Portuguese retrogression, we also hope to show that initial institutions were not to blame for this Iberian episode of the “Little Divergence.” Contrary to the arguments presented in Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2005), Portugal was ruled by a political system not meaningfully distinguishable from England’s until the second half of the seventeenth century (Henriques and Palma Reference Henriques and Palma2023). Portugal’s culture and family-level organization were also not different in relevant dimensions from that of England or the Netherlands (Palma, Reis, and Rodrigues Reference Palma, Reis and Rodrigues2023). Instead, a resource curse provides a compelling alternative conception of the Portuguese problem. Dutch disease caused industry to become less competitive. With access to additional revenues from gold, the Crown no longer needed to negotiate, meaning that, unlike in previous centuries, the Parliament did not meet in the eighteenth century, with power becoming absolute (Palma Reference Palma2020; Henriques and Palma Reference Henriques and Palma2023). The resource curse interrupted the economic and institutional improvement that had been taking place in Portugal during the second half of the seventeenth century. Given the backwardness of institutions and human capital, Portugal’s continued divergence was by then inevitable. Once the gold was gone, Portugal was left with no viable industry, and with a backward institutional and educational system. It then systematically diverged relative to Western Europe, until a partial recovery began to take place only from around the mid-twentieth century (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019, Reference Palma and Reis2021; Amaral Reference Amaral2019).

Footnotes

We are grateful for comments from the editor, Eric Hilt, three anonymous referees, Ernesto Dal Bó, Adam Brzezinski, Hélder Carvalhal, Barry Eichengreen, António Henriques, Karolina Hutková, Kivanç Karaman, Henrique Leitão, Pseudoerasmus, Francisco Malta Romeiras, João Paulo Salvado, Jón Steinsson, Peer Vries, Jacob Weber, and speakers at several conferences and seminars. Special thanks are due to Carlos Javier Charotti and Lukas Leucht. Carlos Santiago-Caballero, Leonor Freire Costa, Henrique Leitão, Leandro Prados de la Escosura, and Francisco Malta Romeiras kindly shared data. Joakim Book and Dehua Li provided excellent research assistance. Financial support to Nuno Palma from Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia (CEECIND/04197/2017) is gratefully acknowledged.

1 See our Online Appendix for a detailed discussion of Portugal’s resource curse in Spain’s reflection.

2 The real exchange rate here can be understood as the relative price of non-traded goods to traded goods (Corden Reference Corden1984).

3 For our data and replication package, see Kedrosky and Palma (2024).

4 For related arguments, see Macedo (1982b, pp. 122, 125, 127).

5 The empirical evidence on resource curse is sometimes focused on short time horizons, which is not ideal. Here, we use more than a century of data and in addition to Dutch disease, we emphasize a complementary political curse, which is always conditional in nature: initial political institutions matter (Robinson, Torvik, and Verdier Reference Robinson, Torvik and Verdier2006; Caselli and Tesei Reference Caselli and Tesei2016; Badia-Miró, Pinilla, and Willebald 2015, p. 3).

6 Sachs and Warner (Reference Sachs and Warner1995), generalize Matsuyama’s framework, and document depressed growth rates in countries for two decades following a year of elevated natural resource exports.

7 The four regions that our data covers correspond to the hinterland areas around Porto, Coimbra, Lisbon, and Évora, following Palma and Reis (Reference Palma and Reis2019). These cover much of the country.

8 Portugal’s economy, measured by output per capita, had been in decline from decades earlier than the Napoleonic invasions (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019). This fact contradicts much Portuguese-language literature claiming that the invasions were the main culprit of Portugal’s decline, for example, Cordeiro (Reference Cordeiro2017, p. 44).

9 Two recent studies find a positive effect of colonial trade on the Portuguese economy, but the authors point out that their results abstract from the possibility of a resource curse; see Costa, Palma, and Reis (Reference Costa, Palma and Reis2015, p. 18) and Palma (Reference Palma2016, pp. 145–46). By contrast, in the present paper, we consider the unintended structural consequences of gold production and imports, which are outside the ambit of their econometric approach, as was previously pointed out by the authors themselves as well as by Abad and Palma (Reference Abad and Palma2021).

10 In Online Appendix A, we provide a detailed summary of the Dutch disease theory and its related literature.

11 Estimates of yearly emigration range from 3,000–4,000 to 8,000–10,000, stalling population growth in Portugal during the first half of the eighteenth century (Palma, Reis, and Zhang Reference Palma, Reis and Zhang2020; Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, p. 166).

12 Upon new gold discoveries, the Crown had the right to a small part of the land, which it then sold (Antonil, Reference Antonil2011, pp. 226–27).

13 For details, see Figure B.1 in Online Appendix B.

14 See our Online Appendix, Table B.1.

15 Portuguese gold became increasingly crucial to the English economy (Palma Reference Palma2018, Reference Palma2020). In exchange for the gold, England sent 18 percent of its manufactured exports and 23 percent of woolens by 1741–5, and well over half of its production of certain manufactured products, especially textiles, for most of the eighteenth century: the textile share in English exports to Portugal hovered between 75 and 85 percent from 1715 to at least 1770 (Fisher Reference Fisher1971, pp. 144–45).

16 Note that by the time the Methuen Treaty was signed in late December 1703, it was known that large quantities of gold likely lasting for decades would be arriving in Portugal from Brazil.

17 In Online Appendix Figure B.2, we show that gold imports as a share of nominal GDP peaked at around 7 percent in the late 1720s and mid-1740s, while generally running at around 5 percent until 1770. These percentages are in the same order of magnitude as those which applied to Spain over the early modern period. For comparative details, see page 24 of the Appendix to Palma (Reference Palma2022) and Chen, Palma, and Ward (Reference Chen, Palma and Ward2021, pp. 3–4).

18 Similar conditions were later offered to the Netherlands (Pedreira Reference Pedreira2005, p. 194).

19 We show the real wage for Portugal in the Online Appendix, Figure B.3.

20 Porto and its hinterland, a region that would gradually become a manufacturing cluster from the late nineteenth century, was as late as the 1820s still unable to compete with imports and not more developed than it had been half a century earlier, in the 1780s, when it was by no means advanced for its time (Cordeiro Reference Cordeiro2017, pp. 12, 56–7).

21 We give details in Online Appendix A.

22 Friedrich List argued that Portugal underwent a period of industrial development between c.1680 and 1700, with manufacturing being destroyed by the Methuen Treaty of 1703 (List Reference List1841).

23 It seems reasonable to assume that if the resource curse associated with Brazilian gold never happened, these would have been constructed.

24 See our Online Appendix A for details.

25 We note in passing that there has been a resurgence of studies suggesting that industrial policy can work, under certain conditions (Juhász, Lane, and Rodrik Reference Juhász, Lane and Rodrik2023; Juhász and Steinwender Reference Juhász and Steinwender2023).

26 Menezes had been a supporter of the 1667 coup, which put the reformist King Pedro II to power, initially as a regent (Lourenço Reference Lourenço2007, p. 124).

27 In the late 1670s, Venetian glass-making craftsmen were brought in to share their knowledge regarding the production of glass and crystal products (Hanson Reference Hanson1981).

28 In 1671, textile craftsmen were brought from Rouen in France to work in Estremoz (Hanson Reference Hanson1981). In 1680, the 17 looms produced 3,000 bolts of cloth, equal to half of the country’s total consumption of baizes and serges; per worker productivity was 5.7 meters per week, exceeding that in the linen sector (4.2 meters). The variable cost of production was 15,000 reis per bolt, each of which could be sold in Lisbon for up to 21,000–22,000 reis. English cloth cost 27,000 reis after shipping and taxes. The program was ultimately abandoned amid political pressure from parties affected by the monopoly, but it demonstrated the potential viability of scaled-up production (Costa, Lains, and Miranda 2016, p. 141).

29 According to standard path dependence or infant industry arguments, industrial development and its associated externalities would have created agglomeration economies likely to survive Brazil’s later loss as a privileged market (Krugman Reference Krugman1987; Melitz Reference Melitz2005).

30 This database is available at http://pwr-portugal.ics.ul.pt/.

31 For example, the almude, a liquid measure, contained 16.8 liters in Lisbon, 25.4 liters in Porto, 16.7 liters in Coimbra, and 17.4 liters in Évora.

32 In the case of soap, low value-to-weight ratios would have hindered the transfer. Neither Fisher (Reference Fisher1963) nor Costa, Lains, and Miranda (2016) list soap as being traded; in any event, soap was purchased in such small quantities that a change of status would have next-to-no effect on our results.

33 There are inevitably some missing values for the prices of certain goods in specific regions for particular years. If a series had too many holes, we substituted it with a comparable good, for example exchanging charcoal for firewood or wax for candles. We fill any remaining gaps by linear interpolation. Online Appendix Table B.5 shows that interpolation was usually unnecessary.

34 We show the figures for Portugal and Lisbon in the text, and for Porto in Online Appendix Figure B.4. We replicate this using the geometric index favored by Malanima (Reference Malanima2013) and find nearly identical results. See Online Appendix Figures B.5, B.6, and B.7.

35 See our Online Appendix for methodological details. We also show there that our results still hold even if we do not make the maize partial substitution (see Figure B.8 of the Online Appendix.)

36 In the Online Appendix, we show that the real exchange rate in the Porto hinterland behaves similarly to those of Portugal and Lisbon (Figure B.4). We also show that London’s equivalent ratio behaves differently: it trends steadily upward with no breaks around 1700 and grows considerably more weakly during the first half of the eighteenth century (Figure B.9). Finally, in Online Appendix Figure B.10, we show the actual traded and non-traded price indices for Portugal to indicate where the changes in their ratio occur.

37 It is important not to exaggerate the importance of the 1755 earthquake. The damage was confined to the south of the country, especially Lisbon (only part of which was destroyed). The number of Lisbon inhabitants who either died or left the city due to the earthquake accounted for only 12 percent of the total, and the city’s population returned to pre-earthquake levels 25 years later (Serrão Reference Serrão2007). Most of Portugal’s population in fact lived in the north (Palma, Reis, and Zhang Reference Palma, Reis and Zhang2020). GDP evidence indicates that the earthquake’s direct impact on the economy was limited (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019).

38 In the baseline results, we include Spain and Holland. However, Spain was also subject to a resource curse during the early modern period, and Holland was subject to Habsburg rule during some of our periods, arguably at least in part until the Peace of Münster (1648), which happened later than the start of our sample period determining pre-treatment weights (1640). In the Online Appendix, (see Figures B.11, B.12, and B.13) we show that the results remain similar if we exclude Spain and Holland. We do not include data for Sweden because of its idiosyncratic monetary situation, due to which it suffered from high levels of inflation in the second half of the eighteenth century (Edvinsson Reference Edvinsson2012; Karaman, Pamuk, and Yıldırım-Karaman Reference Karaman, Pamuk and Yıldırım-Karaman2020). To convert prices from silver to monetary units or vice-versa, as necessary, we relied on Allen (Reference Allen2001) for Germany (based on Leipzig), Malanima (Reference Malanima2013) for Italy (based on Florence), and Karaman, Pamuk, and Yıldırım-Karaman (Reference Karaman, Pamuk and Yıldırım-Karaman2020) for the others.

39 Intuitively, the ridge-augmented SCM permits the use of negative weights to extrapolate from the control units if regular SCM weights do not achieve a near-perfect fit. The first term penalizes imbalances on lagged outcomes and the second term deviations from the weights generated in a standard SCM setting. The hyperparameter governs the extent of permissible extrapolation—if it is high, then the imbalance term is small and the ASCM weights are forced to be close to the regular SCM weights.

40 A confounder for the first decade and a half of the eighteenth century, before the largest quantities of gold arrived, was Portugal’s participation in the War of the Spanish Succession (1701–1714), which was partly fought in Portugal’s territory and had an economic cost that was specific to Portugal, yet orthogonal to the gold finds in Brazil. Portugal’s GDP per capita declined during this period, hitting a trough around 1711–12, a time when hostilities took place in parts of Portugal’s mainland territory.

41 As a robustness check, Online Appendix Figures B.11, B.12, and B.13 show the synthetic control levels dropping in Spain and Holland, while Online Appendix Figures B.14, B.15, B.16) show the gaps. The results are similar. Additionally, Online Appendix Figures B.17 and B.18 show the equivalent figures for our baseline GDP results using population as an additional control. This makes little difference to the overall outcomes. Finally, Online Appendix Figures B.19 and B.20 show the results for the CPI using prices denominated in silver rather than monetary units. Weights for the synthetic control analysis are shown in Online Appendix Tables B.3. and B.4.

42 See Ross (Reference Ross2015) for a review of the political resource curse literature.

43 Over the eighteenth century, the size of Portugal’s deficit had an inverse-U shape, closely tracking the value of gold coin imports over time (Fisher Reference Fisher1971).

44 The viewpoint that the French invasions led to a dramatic fall in industrial development is common in the Portuguese-language literature. It is, for example, defended in some detail by Pedreira (Reference Pedreira1994, p. 298), who however compares nominal export values across time without accounting for inflation. From 1790 to 1805, prices increased by 50 percent, then stabilized until rising again from 1809. Some years later, a persistent deflationary period took place; this volatility implies comparisons must be made in real terms (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2019).

45 Even after the gold inflows stopped in the nineteenth century, Portugal’s economic and political backwardness was hard to overcome.

46 Using a different set of sources and methodologies, Carvalhal and da Silva (Reference Carvalhal and da Silva2019) similarly find that in the 1760s, about half of Portugal’s working population was employed outside of agriculture.

47 Three annual fleets brought large quantities of gold to Portugal annually from Brazilian ports. Most of the money was imported already coined in the colony’s mint houses, and it was delivered to an average of 2,300 recipients (Costa, Rocha, and Brito 2018, p. 1148).

48 Manufacturing, viticulture, and cereal agriculture constituted the lagging traded sector; animal and forest production formed the land-intensive non-traded sector.

49 For example, the Frenchman Ange Goudar noted, in a text later falsely attributed to Pombal, that the discovery of the mines in Brazil in fact made Portugal poorer (Barreto Reference Barreto1982).

50 In turn, Brazil’s long-run development would be negatively affected by a feedback effect due to the inadequate institutional blueprint it was given (Abad and Palma Reference Abad and Palma2021).

51 In prior decades, by contrast, the parliament had considerable power (Henriques and Palma Reference Henriques and Palma2023). It even had ambitions over auditing power, if not direct control of public expenses (Rocha Reference Rocha1896, p. 169).

52 The Inquisition fell under political control and was often used to persecute enemies who were forced to confess they were Jewish even when this was not the case (Saraiva Reference Saraiva1994). On the endogeneity of culture to political institutions, see Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2021).

53 Pombal was a despot who violently murdered his perceived enemies under fabricated charges, while facing no checks and balances. This happened, for example, when he ordered the torture and execution of the Távora family who opposed his power and were falsely incriminated, with their property expropriated. However, he did not limit himself to his peers. In 1757 Pombal suppressed the Innkeepers’ Revolt (Revolta dos Taberneiros), a popular uprising against one of his monopolies, with hundreds arrested and dozens executed. Inhabitants of the city of Porto were ordered to feed the troops sent to suppress the revolt and pay a tax to cover the salaries of soldiers and their munitions.

54 Costa, Lains, and Miranda (2016, p. 216) write that “a small and coherent moneyed elite seems to have been one of the most enduring legacies of his government.”

55 In Online Appendix Table B.2, we list the Jesuit schools open in Portugal by 1759, whose sheer number and size (some with over 1,000 students) suggest that the figure is accurate.

56 A partial catch-up only happened in the twentieth century (Palma and Reis Reference Palma and Reis2021).

57 It is also remarkable that in England, sustained per capita economic growth only began after institutional reforms more than a century following the Reformation, and that within Germany there were no significant differences in outcomes such as income levels, savings, and literacy rates between Catholics and Protestants, except when related to a discriminated Polish minority (Kersting, Wohnsiedler, and Wolf Reference Kersting, Wohnsiedler and Wolf2020).

References

REFERENCES

Abad, Leticia Arroyo, and Palma, Nuno. “The Fruits of El Dorado: The Global Impact of American Precious Metals.” In The Fruits of the Early Globalization, edited by Rafael Dobado-González and Alfredo García-Hiernaux, 95131. Cham, Switzerland: Springer, 2021.10.1007/978-3-030-69666-5_4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abadie, Alberto, Diamond, Alexis, and Hainmueller, Jens. “Comparative Politics and the Synthetic Control Method.” American Journal of Political Science 59, no. 2 (2015): 495510.10.1111/ajps.12116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. “The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth.” American Economic Review 95 (2005): 546–79.10.1257/0002828054201305CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. “Culture, Institutions and Social Equilibria: A Framework.” NBER Working Paper No. 28832, Cambridge, MA, May 2021.Google Scholar
Allen, Robert C.The Great Divergence in European Wages and Prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War.” Explorations in Economic History 38, no. 4 (2001): 411–47.10.1006/exeh.2001.0775CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amaral, Luciano. The Modern Portuguese Economy in the Twentieth and Twenty-first Centuries. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, 2019.10.1007/978-3-030-24548-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antonil, André J. “Cultura e Opulência do Brasil por Suas Drogas e Minas,” vol. 160. Brasília: Edições do Senado Federal, 2011. Originally published in 1711.Google Scholar
Asea, Patrick K., and Lahiri, Amartya. “The Precious Bane.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23 (1999): 823–49.10.1016/S0165-1889(98)00045-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Badia-Miró, Marc, Vicente, Pinilla, and Henry, Willebald, eds. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. London and New York: Taylor & Francis, 2015.10.4324/9781315769356CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barreto, José. “O Discurso Político Falsamente Atribuído ao Marquês do Pombal.” Revista de História das Ideias 4, no. 1 (1982): 385428.10.14195/2183-8925_4-1_14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Michael, Eli, Feller, Avi, and Rothstein, Jesse. “The Augmented Synthetic Control Method.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 116, no. 536 (2021): 1789–803.10.1080/01621459.2021.1929245CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boxer, C. R. The Golden Age of Brazil 1695–1750: Growing Pains of a Colonial Society. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1962.10.1525/9780520318748CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boxer, C. R.Brazilian Gold and British Traders in the First Half of the Eighteenth Century.” Hispanic American Historical Review 49, no. 3 (1969): 454–72.10.1215/00182168-49.3.454CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, Stephen. “Accounting for the Great Divergence: Recent Findings from Historical National Accounting.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP15936, April 2021a.10.1016/B978-0-12-815874-6.00031-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, Stephen. “The Industrial Revolution and the Great Divergence: Recent Findings from Historical National Accounting.” In The Handbook of Historical Economics, edited by Alberto, Bisin and Giovanni, Federico, 749–71. Cambridge, MA: Academic Press, 2021b.Google Scholar
Broadberry, Stephen, Campbell, Bruce M. S., Klein, Alexander, Overton, Mark, and van Leeuwen, Bas. British Economic Growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2015.Google Scholar
Carvalhal, Hélder, and da Silva, Filipa R.. “Occupational Structures and Labour Relations in Portugal, 1750–1800.” Paper presented at the Population, Labour and Wealth in Early Modern Portugal Conference, Universidade do Porto, 2019.Google Scholar
Caselli, Francesco, and Tesei, Andrea. “Resource Windfalls, Political Regimes, and Political Stability.” Review of Economics and Statistics 98, no. 3 (2016): 573–90.10.1162/REST_a_00538CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charotti, Carlos, Palma, Nuno, and Pereira Santos, Joao. “American Treasure and the Decline of Spain.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 17020, February 2022.Google Scholar
Chen, Yao, Palma, Nuno, and Ward, Felix. “Reconstruction of the Spanish Money Supply, 1492–1810.” Explorations in Economic History 81 (2021): 101401.10.1016/j.eeh.2021.101401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Yao, Palma, Nuno, and Ward, Felix. “Goldilocks: American Precious Metals and the Rise of the West.” Technical report, Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, 2022.Google Scholar
Chilosi, David, and Ciccarelli, Carlo. “Evolving Gaps: Occupational Structure in Southern and Northern Italy, 1400–1861.” Economic History Review 75, no. 4 (2022): 1349–78.10.1111/ehr.13159CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cordeiro, José M. L. História da Indústria Portuense. Volume 1 - Dos Finais do Século XVIII a 1852. Porto: Edições Afrontamento, 2017.Google Scholar
Corden, W. Max. “Booming Sector and Dutch Disease Economics: Survey and Consolidation.” Oxford Economic Papers 36 (1984): 359–80.10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a041643CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Max, Corden, W., and Peter Neary, J.. “Booming Sector and De-Industrialisation in a Small Open Economy.” Economic Journal 92 (1982): 825–48.Google Scholar
Costa, Leonor Freiré, Henriques, António, and Palma, Nuno. “Anatomy of a Premodern State.” European Review of Economic History 28, no. 4 (2024): 453–74.10.1093/ereh/heae003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa, Leonor Freiré, Lains, Pedro, and Münch Miranda, Susana. An Economic History of Portugal, 1143–2010. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016.10.1017/CBO9781139565035CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa, Leonor Freiré, Palma, Nuno, and Reis, Jaime. “The Great Escape? The Contribution of the Empire to Portugal’s Economic Growth, 1500–1800.” European Review of Economic History 19 (2015): 122.10.1093/ereh/heu019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa, Leonor Freiré, and Reis, Jaime. “The Chronic Food Deficit of Early Modern Portugal: Curse or Myth?Análise Social 52 (2017): 416–29.Google Scholar
Costa, Leonor Freiré, Manuela Rocha, Maria, and Brito, Paulo B.. “The Alchemy of Gold: Interest Rates, Money Stock, and Credit in Eighteenth-Century Lisbon.” Economic History Review 71, no. 4 (2018): 1147–72.10.1111/ehr.12610CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa, Leonor Freiré, Manuela Rocha, Maria, and Martins de Sousa, Rita. O Ouro do Brasil. Lisbon, Portugal: Imprensa Nacional-Casa da Moeda, 2013.Google Scholar
da Silva, Abílio. Testamento Político de D. Luís da Cunha. Lisboa: Biblioteca Nacional, 2013.Google Scholar
de Sousa, Rita M. Moeda e Metais Preciosos no Portugal Setecentista: 1688–1797. Lisboa: Imprensa Nacional-Casa da Moeda, 2006.Google Scholar
Dias, Luiz Fernando de Carvalho Os Lanifícios na Política Económica do Conde da Ericeira. Lisboa, Portugal, 1954.Google Scholar
Edvinsson, Rodney. “Early Modern Copper Money: Multiple Currencies and Trimetallism in Sweden 1624–1776.” European Review of Economic History 16, no. 4 (2012): 408–29.10.1093/ereh/hes007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernandes, Rogério. Os Caminhos do ABC. Sociedade Portuguesa e Ensino das Primeiras Letras. Porto, Portugal: Porto Editora, 2006.Google Scholar
Fisher, H.Anglo-Portuguese Trade, 1700–1770.” The Economic History Review 16, no. 2 (1963): 219–33.Google Scholar
Fisher, H. The Portugal Trade. Taylor & Francis, 1971.Google Scholar
Forsyth, Peter J., and Nicholas, Stephen J.. “The Decline of Spanish Industry and the Price Revolution: A Neoclassical Analysis.” Journal of European Economic History 12, no. 3 (1983): 601–10.Google Scholar
Francis, A. D. The Methuens and Portugal, 1691–1708. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1966.Google Scholar
Godinho, Vitorino M. Prix et Monnaies au Portugal: 1750–1850. Paris, France: Armand Colin, 1955.Google Scholar
Gollin, Douglas, Jedwab, Remi, and Vollrath, Dietrich. “Urbanization with and without Industrialization.” Journal of Economic Growth 21, no. 1 (2016): 3570.10.1007/s10887-015-9121-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gylfason, Thorvaldur, Herbertsson, Tryggvi, and Zoega, Gylfi. “A Mixed Blessing: Natural Resources and Economic Growth.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 3, no. 2 (1999): 204–25.10.1017/S1365100599011049CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanson, Carl A. Economy and Society in Baroque Portugal, 1668–1703. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press, 1981.10.1007/978-1-349-05878-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hastie, Trevor, Tibshirani, Robert, and Friedman, Jerome. The Elements of Statistical Learning: Data Mining, Inference, and Prediction . Springer Series in Statistics. New York, NY: Springer, 2009.Google Scholar
Henriques, António, and Palma, Nuno. “Comparative European Institutions and the Little Divergence, 1385–1800.” Journal of Economic Growth 28 (2023): 259–94.10.1007/s10887-022-09213-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Juhász, Réka, Lane, Nathan J., and Rodrik, Dani. “The New Economics of Industrial Policy.” Annual Review of Economics 16 (2023): 213–42.10.1146/annurev-economics-081023-024638CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Juhász, Réka, and Steinwender, Claudia. “Industrial Policy and the Great Divergence.” Annual Review of Economics 16 (2023): 2754.10.1146/annurev-economics-091523-044259CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karaman, K. K., Pamuk, Ş., and Yıldırım-Karaman, S.. “Money and Monetary Stability in Europe, 1300–1914.” Journal of Monetary Economics 115 (2020): 279300.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2019.07.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kedrosky, Davis, and Palma, Nuno. Replication for “The Cross of Gold: Brazilian Treasure and the Decline of Portugal.” Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2024-10-04. https://doi.org/10.3886/E209481V1 Google Scholar
Keibek, S. A. J. “The Male Occupational Structure of England and Wales, 1600–1850.” PhD thesis, University of Cambridge, 2017.Google Scholar
Kersting, Felix, Wohnsiedler, Iris, and Wolf, Nikolas. “Weber Revisited: The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Nationalism.” Journal of Economic History 80, no. 3 (2020): 710–45.10.1017/S0022050720000364CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krantz, Olle. “Swedish GDP 1300–1560: A Tentative Estimate.” Department of Economic History, Lund University, 2017.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul. “The Narrow Moving Band, the Dutch Disease, and the Competitive Consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: Notes on Trade in the Presence of Dynamic Scale Economies.” Journal of Development Economics 27 (1987): 4155.10.1016/0304-3878(87)90005-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leitão, Henrique. A Ciência na “Aula da Esfera” no Colégio de Santo Antão, 1590–1759. Comissariado Geral das Comemorações do V Centenário do Nascimento de São Francisco de Xavier, 2007.Google Scholar
Leitão, Henrique, and Romeiras, Francisco M.. “The Role of Science in the History of Portuguese Anti-Jesuitism.” Journal of Jesuit Studies 2, no. 1 (2015): 7799.10.1163/22141332-00201004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, Friedrich. The National System of Political Economy. London: Longmans, Green, and Company, 1841.Google Scholar
Lourenço, Maria P. M. D. Pedro II. Lisboa: Círculo de Leitores, 2007.Google Scholar
Macedo, Jorge Borges de. Problemas de História da Indústria Portuguesa no Século XVIII. Querco, 1982a.Google Scholar
Macedo, Jorge Borges de. A Situação Económica no Tempo de Pombal: Alguns Aspectos. Moraes Editora, 1982b.Google Scholar
Madureira, Nuno L. Mercado e Privilégios: A Indústria Portuguesa Entre 1750 e 1834. Lisboa: Editorial Estampa, 1997.Google Scholar
Magalhães, J. R. “O Império.” In História Económica de Portugal, edited by Pedro Lains and Álvaro Ferreira da Silva. Lisboa: Instituto de Ciências Sociais, 2005.Google Scholar
Malanima, Paolo. L’economia italiana: dalla crescita medievale alla crescita contemporanea. Mulino, 2002.Google Scholar
Malanima, Paolo. “The Long Decline of a Leading Economy: GDP in Central and Northern Italy, 1300–1913.” European Review of Economic History 15, no. 2 (2011): 169219.10.1017/S136149161000016XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malanima, Paolo. “When Did England Overtake Italy? Medieval and Early Modern Divergence in Prices and Wages.” European Review of Economic History 17, no. 1 (2013): 4570.10.1093/ereh/hes022CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuyama, Kiminori. “Agricultural Productivity, Comparative Advantage, and Economic Growth.” Journal of Economic Theory 58 (1992): 317–34.10.1016/0022-0531(92)90057-OCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melitz, Marc J.When and How Should Infant Industries be Protected?Journal of International Economics 66, no. 1 (2005): 177–96.10.1016/j.jinteco.2004.07.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meneses, A. F. d. “A Economia.” In Nova História de Portugal, edited by António Henrique R. de Oliveira Marques and Joel Serrão, 23–41. Lisboa: Editorial Presença, 2001.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” Journal of Economic History 49, no. 4 (1989): 803–32.10.1017/S0022050700009451CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palma, Nuno. “Sailing Away from Malthus: Intercontinental Trade and European Economic Growth, 1500–1800.” Cliometrica 10, no. 2 (2016): 129–49.10.1007/s11698-015-0126-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palma, Nuno. “Money and Modernization in Early Modern England.” Financial History Review 25, no. 3 (2018): 231–61.10.1017/S0968565018000185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palma, Nuno. “American Precious Metals and Their Consequences for Early Modern Europe.” In Handbook of the History of Money and Currency, edited by Stefano Battilossi, Youssef Cassis, and Kazuhiko Yago. Singapore: Springer, 2020.Google Scholar
Palma, Nuno. “The Real Effects of Monetary Expansions: Evidence from a Largescale Historical Experiment.” Review of Economic Studies 89, no. 3 (2022): 1593–627.10.1093/restud/rdab042CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palma, Nuno, and Reis, Jaime. “From Convergence to Divergence: Portuguese Economic Growth, 1527–1850.” Journal of Economic History 79, no. 2 (2019): 477506.10.1017/S0022050719000056CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palma, Nuno, and Reis, Jaime. “Can Autocracy Promote Literacy? Evidence from a Cultural Alignment Success Story.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 186 (2021): 412–36.10.1016/j.jebo.2021.02.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palma, Nuno P., Reis, Jaime, and Rodrigues, Lisbeth. “Historical Gender Discrimination Does Not Explain Comparative Western European Development: Evidence from Portugal, 1300–1900.” Explorations in Economic History 88 (2023): 101481.10.1016/j.eeh.2022.101481CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palma, Nuno, Reis, Jaime, and Zhang, Mengtian. “Reconstruction of Regional and National Population Using Intermittent Census-Type Data: The Case of Portugal, 1527–1864.” Historical Methods: A Journal of Quantitative and Interdisciplinary History 53, no. 1 (2020): 1127.10.1080/01615440.2019.1666762CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pedreira, Jorge. Estrutura Industrial e Mercado Colonial: Portugal e Brasil (1780–1830). Lisboa: Difel, 1994.Google Scholar
Pedreira, Jorge. “A Indústria.” In História Económica de Portugal, edited by Pedro Lains and Álvaro Ferreira da Silva, 177–208. Lisboa: Instituto de Ciências Sociais, 2005.Google Scholar
Pfister, Ulrigh. “Economic Growth in Germany, 1500–1850.” Journal of Economic History 82, no. 4 (2022): 1071–107.10.1017/S002205072200033XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prados de la Escosura, Leandro, Carlos, Álvarez-Nogal, and Carlos, Santiago-Caballero. “Growth Recurring in Preindustrial Spain?Cliometrica 16, no. 2 (2022): 215–41.10.1007/s11698-021-00232-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reis, Jaime. “How Poor Was the European Periphery Before 1850?” In The Mediterranean Response to Globalization Before 1950, edited by Şevket Pamuk and Jeffrey G. Williamson. London: Routledge, 2002.Google Scholar
Reis, Jaime. “Economic Growth, Human Capital Formation and Consumption in Western Europe Before 1800.” In Living Standards in the Past: New Perspectives on Well-Being in Asia and Europe, edited by Robert C. Allen, Tommy Bengtsson, and Martin Dribe, 195225. Oxford: University Press Oxford, 2005.10.1093/0199280681.003.0009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reis, Jaime. “Gross Agricultural Output: A Quantitative, Unified Perspective, 1500–1850.” In An Agrarian History of Portugal, 1000–2000: Economic Development on the European Frontier. Leiden, Netherlands: Brill, 2017.Google Scholar
Ridolfi, Leonardo, and Nuvolari, Alessandro. “L’histoire Immobile? A Reappraisal of French Economic Growth Using the Demand-Side Approach, 1280–1850.” European Review of Economic History 25, no. 3 (2021): 405–28.10.1093/ereh/heab012CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, James A., Torvik, Ragnar, and Verdier, Thierry. “Political Foundations of the Resource Curse.” Journal of Development Economics 79, no. 2 (2006): 447–68.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2006.01.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rocha, Manuel A. C. Ensaio Sobre a Historia do Governo e Legislação de Portugal: Para Servir de Introdução ao Estudo do Direito Patrio. Coimbra, Portugal: Imprensa da Universidade de Coimbra, 1896.Google Scholar
Romeiras, Francisco M.The Pombaline Expulsion and the Building of Anti-Jesuitism.” In Jesuits and the Book of Nature, 23–41. Leiden, Netherlands: Brill, 2019.10.1163/9789004382367CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romeiras, Francisco M., and Leitão, Henrique. “The Rise and Fall of Jesuit Education in Portugal, 1540–1759.” Unpublished manuscript, 2022.Google Scholar
Ross, Michael L.What Have We Learned about the Resource Curse?Annual Review of Political Science 18 (2015): 239–59.10.1146/annurev-polisci-052213-040359CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, Jeffrey, and Warner, Andrew. “Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth.” NBER Working Paper No. 5398, Cambridge, MA, December 1995.Google Scholar
Saraiva, António José. Inquisição e Cristãos-Novos. Lisboa: Editorial Estampa, 1994.Google Scholar
Schön, Lennart, and Krantz, Olle. “New Swedish Historical National Accounts since the 16th Century in Constant and Current Prices.” Lund University, Department of Economic History, 2015.Google Scholar
Serrão, Jose Vicente. “Os Impactos Económicos do Terremoto.” In O Terramoto de 1755: Impactos Históricos, edited by Ana C. Araújo, José L. Cardoso, and Nuno G. Monteiro. Lisboa: Livros Horizonte, 2007.Google Scholar
Smits, Jan-Pieter, Horlings, Edwin, and Luiten van Zanden, Jan. “Dutch GNP and Its Components, 1800–1913.” Monograph, 2000.Google Scholar
Stein, Stanley J., and Stein, Barbara H.. Silver, Trade, and War: Spain and America in the Making of Early Modern Europe. Baltimore and London: John Hopkins University Press, 2000.10.56021/9780801861352CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stolz, Yvonne, Baten, Joerg, and Reis, Jaime. “Portuguese Living Standards, 1720–1980, in European Comparison: Heights, Income, and Human Capital.” Economic History Review 66, no. 2 (2013): 545–78.10.1111/j.1468-0289.2012.00658.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
TePaske, John J. A New World of Gold and Silver. Leiden, Netherlands: Brill, 2010.10.1163/ej.9789004188914.i-342CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wijnbergen, Van, Sweder. “The ‘Dutch Disease’: A Disease after All?” Economic Journal 94 (1984): 4155.10.2307/2232214CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Zanden, Jan Luiten, and van Leeuwen, Bas. “Persistent but not Consistent: The Growth of National Income in Holland 1347–1807.” Explorations in Economic History 49, no. 2 (2012): 119–30.10.1016/j.eeh.2011.11.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 GDP PER CAPITA OF SELECTED WESTERN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES IN CONSTANT PRICES (“INTERNATIONAL” GEARY-KHAMIS DOLLARS OF 1990)

Figure 1

Figure 1 SHARES OF POPULATION OUTSIDE AGRICULTURE FOR EUROPEAN COUNTRIESSources: Keibek (2017) for England; Palma and Reis (2019) for Portugal; Ridolfi and Nuvolari (2021) for France; Chilosi and Ciccarelli (2022) for Italy. Figures for Spain derived by back projecting from urban population shares adjusted to net out urban dwellers living on agriculture, using the average of the labor share in 1787 and 1797 as a benchmark, according to the population census for these two years (66.1 percent) (Prados de la Escosura, Álvarez-Nogal, and Santiago-Caballero 2022). We thank Leandro Prados de la Escosura for this suggestion.

Figure 2

Figure 2 GOLD EXPORTS AS A PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL EXPORTS (INCLUDING GOLD)Sources: Figures for gold derived from Costa, Rocha, and de Sousa (2013), cited with export figures in Costa, Lains, and Miranda (2016, p. 205).

Figure 3

Table 2 TRADED AND NON-TRADED CATEGORIES AND WEIGHTS

Figure 4

Figure 3 RATIO OF NON-TRADED TO TRADED PRICE INDICES FOR PORTUGAL, 1650–1820Notes: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal. The price index shown here corresponds to an 11-year moving average.Sources: Price data from PWR. Gold production in Portuguese Brazil from TePaske (2010).

Figure 5

Figure 4 RATIO OF NON-TRADED TO TRADED PRICE INDICES FOR LISBON, 1650–1820Note: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal.Sources: Price data from PWR. Gold production in Portuguese Brazil from TePaske (2010).

Figure 6

Figure 5 SYNTHETIC CONTROL RESULTS FOR PORTUGUESE CPI, 1640–1800Notes: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal. As a robustness check, in Online Appendix Figure B.21 we show the same figure using an unweighted mean, rather than the synthetic counterfactual, and demonstrate that the result is largely unaffected.Source: See Table 1.

Figure 7

Figure 6 SYNTHETIC CONTROL RESULTS FOR PORTUGUESE GDP, 1640–1800Notes: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal. As a robustness check, in Online Appendix Figure B.22 we show the same figure using an unweighted mean, rather than the synthetic counterfactual, and demonstrate that the result is largely unaffected.Source: See Table 1.

Figure 8

Figure 7 SYNTHETIC CONTROL RESULTS FOR PORTUGUESE GDP PER CAPITA, 1640–1800Notes: The vertical line in 1694 marks the approximate beginning of gold imports to Portugal. As a robustness check, in Online Appendix Figure B.23 we show the same figure using an unweighted mean, rather than the synthetic counterfactual, and demonstrate that the result is largely unaffected.Source: See Table 1.

Supplementary material: File

Kedrosky and Palma supplementary material

Kedrosky and Palma supplementary material
Download Kedrosky and Palma supplementary material(File)
File 1.1 MB