Hostname: page-component-6bb9c88b65-6vlrh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-07-25T14:43:48.080Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Are mandatory oaths effective in groups?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 July 2025

Sorravich Kingsuwankul*
Affiliation:
School of Business and Economics, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam, HV Amsterdam, The Netherlands Tinbergen Institute, MS Amsterdam, Netherlands
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Previous studies have shown that an oath can reduce lying in individual settings. Can it reduce lying in groups, a context where lying is more prevalent? Results from a lab experiment reveal that the impact depends on the incentive structures and procedures. A mandatory oath reduces lying when group members’ payoffs are independent, but only has a marginal effect when payoffs are dependent. Voluntary oath-taking enhances the effectiveness under both incentive structures by fostering intrinsic motivation to keep promises. The findings highlight the importance of peer effects and oath-taking procedures on the effectiveness of an oath in group settings.

Information

Type
Original Paper
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Economic Science Association.

1. Introduction

Dishonest behavior is commonplace in societies – from misreporting on an income tax form to committing frauds in professional settings. Recent studies in behavioral economics suggest that individuals experience non-pecuniary costs of lying arising from an intrinsic preference to be honest and a desire to be seen as honest (Gneezy et al., Reference Gneezy, Kajackaite and Sobel2018, Dufwenberg & Dufwenberg, Reference Dufwenberg and Dufwenberg2018, Abeler et al., Reference Abeler, Nosenzo and Raymond2019, Schudy et al., Reference Schudy, Grundmann and Spantig2024). However, even with these preferences for truth-telling, individuals may feel tempted to cheat in certain situations. Therefore, interventions aimed at increasing the costs of lying can be effective in reducing dishonest behavior. One such intervention is an oath – a moral commitment where individuals promise to be honest.

Previous studies have shown an oath to be effective in individual settings (e.g., Jacquemet et al., Reference Jacquemet, Luchini, Rosaz and Shogren2019, Beck, Reference Beck2021). Yet, little is known about its effectiveness in groups. In an individual setting, an oath-taker relies primarily on own preferences and beliefs to guide behavior. A group context introduces heterogeneity in preferences and diverse perceptions of social norms, which can influence the oath’s effectiveness. If an individual feels morally engaged by the oath, but their peers do not share this sentiment, how would that affect their behavior? Does peer influence erode the honesty norm, or conversely reinforce it and thus the oath’s impact? Addressing these questions is relevant if one’s goal is to understand the mechanisms of an oath in a more general setting where social interactions are inherent, such as that of an organization.

The goal of this study is to assess the impact of an oath in a group setting with social interactions. The study focuses on two peer effects, namely contagion and pressure – both of which can moderate the impact of an oath. Contagion refers to how an individual can be influenced by what their peers think or do. The literature (reviewed in the next section) have shown that in the absence of an oath, individuals condition their behavior on that of their peers and are more susceptible to others’ norm violation than norm compliance. Such asymmetric behavioral contagion can be explained by an erosion of norms. Since an oath should increase the non-pecuniary costs of lying and make the injunctive norm (‘what one ought to do’) more salient, one can expect the oath to put a moral constraint on individuals, thereby reducing dishonesty and limiting its contagion.

Besides complying with peers, an individual in a group may face peer pressure, which arises when their actions have collective consequences for the group. In such cases, they may feel compelled to act in line with peers’ expectations to avoid social costs.Footnote 1 Unlike contagion, this type of group conformism is not driven by internalizing peers’ normative views, but by the desire to meet their expectation and avoid actions that the group deems suboptimal or contradictory to the ‘group norm.’ If the honesty norm becomes salient but fails to emerge as a group norm, peer pressure can crowd-out the impact of the oath in group settings by encouraging individuals to lie to live up to peers’ expectation. However, if honesty becomes the predominant norm, peer pressure can reinforce the impact of the oath.

As social interactions can potentially undermine or promote the norm of honesty in group settings, the success of oath interventions in fostering honesty may depend not only on their presence but also on how they are administered – whether they are mandatory or voluntary. Mandating an oath ensures universal participation but may diminish its intrinsic meaning by depriving individuals of autonomy. In contrast, a voluntary oath preserves autonomy, potentially enhancing the intrinsic motivation to be honest among those who take it. These different perceptions of an oath can influence the social interactions within groups, thereby shaping the emergence of the honesty norm and consequently the oath’s effectiveness. This understanding can provide informative insights for policymakers on how to design oath interventions in a context where peer effects naturally exist.Footnote 2

A laboratory experiment, conducted with 712 participants, uses a variant of the observed cheating game developed by Gneezy et al. Reference Gneezy, Kajackaite and Sobel(2018). In this game, participants observe a video of a die roll via the computer, are asked to memorize the outcome and to report it later. Since the payoff depends on the reported number, participants have the opportunity to misreport to earn additional payoffs. This setup allows the experimenter to infer lying at an individual level (ex-post). The experiment uses a mixed experimental design, varying the settings (individual or group) as a within-subjects dimension, and the incentive structure, the presence of the oath, its procedure as a between-subjects dimension.

The within-subjects dimension consists of three successive parts. In part 1, participants play the game in an individual setting without the possibility to interact with other participants. The decision in part 1 is used as a proxy for individual type (honest or dishonest). In part 2, participants play the same game but in a group setting. They are randomly matched to form a group of three. All the three members first observe the same video of a die roll, after which they can use an anonymous computerized free-form chat for five minutes. The chat enables group members to interact and thus peer effects to occur. After the chat, group members report the number individually. The decision in part 2 is the main outcome of interest in this study. Finally, in part 3, participants play the game in an individual setting as in part 1.

The between-subjects dimension is introduced at the beginning of part 2 in a 2x3 design. Peer effects are introduced by varying the incentive structures, which differ in whether group members are subject to the payoff commonality rule (Kocher et al., Reference Kocher, Schudy and Spantig2018). In No Payoff Commonality (NPC) treatment, monetary incentives mirror those in the individual setting; the number reported by an individual determines their own payoff without affecting the payoffs of other group members. As such, only contagion influences group members’ decisions through communication. In Payoff Commonality (PC) treatment, the payoffs of members are dependent; all members must report the same number to earn the payoff, otherwise they earn nothing. Under this rule, individuals can be pressured by peers to enter a specific number depending on what emerges as the majority opinion in the group. If the group norm is to maximize payoffs by lying, peer pressure should work against the oath, reducing its effectiveness under this incentive structure. On the other hand, if the group norm is to be honest, peer pressure should promote honest coordination.

To examine the impact of an oath and its procedure, the two incentive structures are interacted with the three oath treatments. In the No-Oath treatment, participants do not swear any oath. This serves as a baseline level of lying in groups. In the Mandatory Oath (Mand-Oath) treatment, participants swear a mandatory oath at the beginning of part 2 to tell the truth for the rest of the experiment. Lastly, in the Voluntary Oath (Vol-Oath) treatment, participants are offered the same oath, but are free to sign it or not.Footnote 3 The impact of a mandatory oath on lying in groups can be assessed by comparing the No-Oath and Mand-Oath treatments, while the impact of making the oath voluntary can be extracted by comparing the Vol-Oath and Mand-Oath treatments. The voluntary nature of the oath is expected to enhance its impact by reinforcing the intrinsic motivation associated with a voluntary commitment.

Results from the experiment confirm that oaths can be effective in groups. In the absence of an oath and the presence of peer effects, relying on preferences for truth-telling alone is clearly insufficient as more than 90% of individuals lie in groups. Introducing a mandatory oath reduces the likelihood to lie in groups by nearly 20 percentage points when group members’ payoffs are independent. However, the impact is marginal under the payoff commonality rule. These results suggest that a mandatory oath can be effective in settings where dishonesty is contagious but its impact can be crowded out by peer pressure to lie for the group’s financial gain. Allowing an oath to be taken voluntarily enhances its effectiveness further by nearly 20 percentage points under both incentive structures, potentially due to a stronger intrinsic motivation to uphold a voluntary oath. Additional analyses reveal that, while the oath changes the behavior of both honest and dishonest types, an increased intrinsic motivation arising from the voluntary procedure primarily comes from the honest types. Overall, these results indicate that to be impactful in a context where peer effects are present, the oath must be designed in close connection with the incentive structures and procedures.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the related literature. Section 3 outlines the experimental design and procedure. Section 4 reports the results. Section 5 discusses these findings and concludes.

2. Related Literature

This study contributes to the literature on the effect of an oath on lying. Most prior studies focused on individual settings and showed that it induces truth-telling (Jacquemet et al., Reference Jacquemet, Luchini, Rosaz and Shogren2019, Beck, Reference Beck2021). A general interpretation is that the oath raises moral awareness and interferes with the justification process. Under oath, the costs of lying increase because doing so involves two moral transgressions (i.e., telling a lie and breaking an oath). This makes lying under oath less attractive.Footnote 4 Two recent studies have shown an oath to be effective in group settings (Dunaiev & Khadjavi, Reference Dunaiev and Khadjavi2021, Zickfeld et al., Reference Zickfeld, Ścigała, Weiss, Michael and Mitkidis2023). The contribution of the current study goes beyond simply showing that an oath works in groups; it aims to understand how it can be effective in such a context by examining the influence of peers and the social information they transmit. These peer effects are not examined in the two studies.

The literature on peer effects and lying has shown that individuals are more likely to cheat in the presence of peers (e.g.,Weisel & Shalvi, Reference Weisel and Shalvi2015, Kocher et al., Reference Kocher, Schudy and Spantig2018, Bäker & Mechtel, Reference Bäker and Mechtel2019). Among various mechanisms proposed to explain this phenomenon, this study focuses on contagion, which refers to how individuals adjust their behavior in response to what their peers think or do.Footnote 5 The notion of contagion can be applied to both honest and dishonest behaviors; however, most prior studies found that dishonesty is more contagious than honesty (seeKeizer et al., Reference Keizer, Lindenberg and Steg2008, Fosgaard et al., Reference Fosgaard, Hansen and Piovesan2013, Kroher & Wolbring, Reference Kroher and Wolbring2015, Diekmann et al., Reference Diekmann, Przepiorka and Rauhut2015). For instance, Lauer and Untertrifaller Reference Lauer and Untertrifaller(2019) found that individuals condition their decision to lie on that of their peers.Footnote 6 Further, there is evidence that people prefer being paired with a peer of the same type to reduce the moral cost of norm violation (e.g.,Gross et al., Reference Gross, Leib, Offerman and Shalvi2018, Charroin et al., Reference Charroin, Fortin and Villeval2022). This study contributes to this literature by examining whether an oath reduces lying in a setting where dishonesty is contagious.

The asymmetry in contagion can be explained by the information conveyed through peers’ norm violation about the underlying empirical norms (‘what others are actually doing’) as opposed to the injunctive norms (‘what one ought to do’). While most people would agree that lying is socially inappropriate, knowing that others actually lie allows individuals to justify their lies. This is consistent with the finding of Bicchieri et al. Reference Bicchieri, Dimant and Sonderegger(2023) who showed that individuals distort their beliefs about the empirical norms to license their lies. Similarly, Dimant et al. Reference Dimant, Galeotti and Villeval(2024) found that people selectively sample lenient information about the empirical norms to facilitate lying. An oath is expected to limit the contagion of dishonesty as individuals are committed to keep the promise to be honest (Ellingsen & Johannesson, Reference Ellingsen and Johannesson2004, Charness & Dufwenberg, Reference Charness and Dufwenberg2006, Vanberg, Reference Vanberg2008).

This study further contributes by examining peer pressure as a mechanism distinct from contagion. Kandel and Lazear Reference Kandel and Lazear(1992) models peer pressure as a non-pecuniary social motivation that drives individuals to take certain actions under a team incentive. According to Kandel and Lazear Reference Kandel and Lazear(1992), when an individual’s action determines the group’s payoff, peer pressure prevents individuals from shirking as the action is perceived as suboptimal for the group. Without punishment opportunities and observability by peers, Kandel and Lazear Reference Kandel and Lazear(1992) conceptualizes peer pressure as a social cost borne by those whose action deviates from the ‘group norm’ (as inKrupka & Weber, Reference Krupka and Weber2013).Footnote 7 In the context of this study, if an individual’s decision affects group members’ payoffs, depending on what is perceived as an optimal action for the group or a group norm, peer pressure can encourage individuals to take an action that is consistent with the majority opinion.

To examine the role of peer pressure on the impact of an oath, the study varies the types of incentive structures group members face, and considers the case of the payoff commonality rule (Kocher et al., Reference Kocher, Schudy and Spantig2018). Under this rule, group members must coordinate their actions, as failure to do so results in a collective loss. This resembles, for example, decision-making in a committee, where the decisions of all members have material consequences for the group. While the oath reinforces the honesty norm, the group incentive fosters a preference for profit maximization, leading to two competing norms. If the majority prefers to maximize group payoffs, peer pressure can erode the honesty norm and compel an individual to lie. However, if honesty emerges as a group norm, peer pressure may compel individuals to be honest, as deviating from the predominant norm is costly – financially for the group and socially for the individual.

Lastly, the study contributes to a better understanding of how oath-taking procedures matter for its effectiveness in groups. Prior studies have demonstrated that an oath is effective whether it is mandatory (e.g.,Davis & Jaber-Lopez, Reference Davis and Jaber-Lopez2022) or voluntary (e.g.,Jacquemet et al., Reference Jacquemet, Luchini, Rosaz and Shogren2019). Procedural differences may matter in group settings as social interactions within groups can erode or foster the honesty norm. On the one hand, a mandatory oath is externally imposed and restricts the freedom of choice. This may cause some individuals to perceive an oath as less meaningful, weakening intrinsic motivation. Voluntary oath-taking, on the other hand, preserves autonomy which can reinforce intrinsic motivation to be honest.Footnote 8 Consequently, the differences in oath-taking procedures may give rise to different levels of honesty norm and thus the success of oath interventions. Understanding the extent to which different procedures influence honesty in groups and how they interact with peer effects can be useful in designing effective interventions in an organizational context.

3. Experimental Design and Procedures

3.1. Design

Participants play an observed cheating game (Gneezy et al., Reference Gneezy, Kajackaite and Sobel2018). They observe a video displaying an outcome of a die roll on the computer screen (i.e., , , , , , or ), which has been randomly selected by the program. Each face of the die is associated with different payoffs: for one token, for two tokens, and so on. The exception is for , which yields zero tokens. Participants are asked to memorize the outcome of the die roll and to report it later. They earn the payoff depending on their report, and therefore can misreport to earn more tokens.

A mixed experimental design, similar to that of Kocher et al. Reference Kocher, Schudy and Spantig(2018), is used.Footnote 9 The within-subjects dimension consists of three successive parts, and varies in whether the observed cheating game is played in an individual or a group setting. In part 1, the game is played in an individual setting, as described above. The decision in part 1 serves as a control variable for individual types. In part 2, participants are randomly matched to form a group of three. The three members view the same video of a die roll, after which they can chat anonymously for five minutes via computer. It is through this chat that peer effects operate in the experiment. The chat allows for a free-form communication apart from revealing identity. Messages are shown to all group members. Participants can leave the chat at any point of time. The chat ends either after all group members have left the chat or the time has elapsed. After the chat, each group member makes an individual report as in part 1. The decision in part 2 is the main outcome measure in this study. Finally, in part 3, participants play the game individually, as they did in part 1. The decision in part 3 will be used to examine any spillover effects from the group to the individual setting. No feedback is given regarding the decisions of other participants.

The between-subjects dimension is introduced at the beginning of part 2 in a 2x3 design, while part 1 remains the same across treatments. The presence of peer effects is introduced via the two incentive structures namely No Payoff Commonality and Payoff Commonality.

No Payoff Commonality (‘NPC’) treatment: In the NPC treatment, participants faced an individual incentive structure where the payoffs of group members were independent. They were informed that the number they reported would not affect the payoff of their group members, and vice versa. Therefore, in this treatment, the incentive in part 2 is the same as in the individual setting (part 1 and 3), but allows for contagion via group communication. Peer pressure is absent in the NPC treatment as group members’ actions do not impact the payoffs of one another.

Payoff Commonality (‘PC’) treatment: In the PC treatment, participants faced a group incentive structure where the payoffs of group members were dependent. They were informed that all the three members must report the same number to earn the payoff associated with that number; otherwise, they earned nothing. This incentive structure requires group members to coordinate on their individual reports and can build an expectation in favor of certain numbers. Consistent with Kandel and Lazear Reference Kandel and Lazear(1992), the design satisfies the two pre-requisites for peer pressure: collective consequences (profit sharing) and a means to exert pressure (communication). Therefore, the payoff commonality rule generates peer pressure, alongside contagion.

The two incentive structures are interacted with three oath treatments that vary in whether and how an oath is introduced.

No-Oath treatment: In the No-Oath treatment, participants played the game in a group setting without taking any oath.

Mandatory Oath (‘Mand-Oath’) treatment: In the Mand-Oath treatment, all participants had to individually swear an oath by which they committed to be honest and to tell the truth for the rest of the experiment. The oath-taking was done before knowing the instructions of part 2. To take the oath, participants re-typed the text on their computers.Footnote 10 The oath-taking was common-knowledge.

Voluntary Oath (‘Vol-Oath’) treatment: In the Vol-Oath treatment, all participants were offered the same oath (as in the Mand-Oath treatment) but were free to sign it. To ensure that participants did not sign for fear of exclusion from the session and the potential earnings, they were additionally informed that their decision to sign the oath would not affect their participation in any way and that the experimenter would not inform other participants of their decision. This was common-knowledge.Footnote 11 On the same screen, participants were asked whether or not they would like to take the oath by clicking on the button ‘I agree’ or ‘I disagree’. Those who agreed to take the oath retyped it as in the Mand-Oath treatment, while those who disagreed retyped a neutral sentence.Footnote 12

This results in six between-subjects treatments namely, No-Oath NPC, No-Oath-PC, Mand-Oath NPC, Mand-Oath PC, Vol-Oath NPC, and Vol-Oath PC. Moving from No-Oath to Mand-Oath, the treatment variations assess the impact of a mandatory oath in reducing lies in groups with different peer effects (contagion in the NPC treatments, and contagion and pressure in the PC treatments). Finally, moving from Mand-Oath to Vol-Oath, the treatment variations evaluate the extent to which the voluntary nature of the oath, and the intrinsic motivation it fosters, enhances its effectiveness.

In addition to the six main treatments, one control condition (‘Mand-Oath Indiv’) was conducted where participants took a mandatory oath at the beginning of part 2 but played in the game in an individual setting. This will be used to assess the impact of a mandatory oath in the absence of any peer effects and to help disentangle them (see section 4.3 on the mechanisms).

3.2. Belief Elicitation

After completing the three parts of the experiment, all participants answered three incentivized belief questions about the empirical norms in each part of the experiment. The belief elicitation was not announced and came as a surprise. The focus is on the belief about the proportion of participants reporting ‘5’. At the end of the experiment, one of the three belief questions was randomly selected by the program for a bonus payment.

Finally, after the belief elicitation, participants completed a standard socio-demographic questionnaire, witnessed the randomization of payment for their decisions (more details in the next section) and received feedback about their payoff for all parts and the selected belief question. The design, behavioral conjectures and the number of observations were pre-registered prior to data collection at AsPredicted.org (#79968 and #171934).

3.3. Procedures

The experiment was run in-person at GATE-Lab in Lyon, France. Twenty-three sessions were conducted between November and December 2021 with 408 participants for the No-Oath NPC, No-Oath PC, Mand-Oath NPC, and Mand-Oath PC treatments.Footnote 13 Seventeen sessions were conducted between April and June 2024 with 304 participants for the Vol-Oath NPC, Vol-Oath PC, and Mand-Oath Indiv treatments.Footnote 14 All participants (55.62% females) were recruited via HRoot (Bock et al., Reference Bock, Baetge and Nicklisch2014), mainly from local engineering and business schools.

The experiment was programmed using z-Tree (Fischbacher, Reference Fischbacher2007). As in Kocher et al. Reference Kocher, Schudy and Spantig(2018), the randomization of the videos of the die outcomes was conducted for the first two sessions and then used for the rest of the sessions to increase statistical power and simplify treatment comparisons.Footnote 15 Upon arrival, participants randomly drew a ticket from an opaque bag which assigned them to computer terminals. A general instruction was given and read aloud at the start of the session. The remaining instructions (from part 1 onwards) were shown on computer screens at the beginning of each part. The average duration of the sessions was 50 minutes. Full instructions are reported in Online Appendix A.

At the end of the session, the additional payoffs were determined. For the decisions, the experimenter randomly selected one participant to draw a raffle. The raffle indicated a participant ID who then rolled a six-sided die. The outcome of this die roll determined which part of the experiment (1, 2, or 3) was payoff relevant. This procedure was described in the general instruction.

After determining and announcing which part determined the payoff for their decisions, participants received feedback on the payoffs of all parts, including the bonus earned from the belief question (randomly selected by the program). The average payment was 15.50 Euros (SD = 3.76), including a fixed fee of 5 Euros.Footnote 16

4. Results

The results section is organized as follows. Section 4.1 assesses the impact of an oath on lying in groups under different incentive structures and procedures. Section 4.2 conducts a heterogeneity analysis to assess the treatment effects conditional on a given level of preferences for truth-telling. Section 4.3 explores the mechanisms of contagion and peer pressure.

4.1. The impact of an oath on lying in groups

This section evaluates the impact of an oath on the decision to lie in groups under different incentive structures and procedures. The participant is classified as a liar if they report a different number than the one shown in the video of the die roll.Footnote 17 An intention-to-treat strategy is used to preserve treatment assignments and assess the overall treatment effects. While oath-taking was exogenous in the Mand-Oath treatments, participants in the Vol-Oath treatments were free to sign the oath. Indeed, only 71.01% of participants swore the oath when it was voluntary.Footnote 18 Using an intention-to-treat strategy, an analysis is performed on the entire sample (i.e., including the non oath-takers in the Vol-Oath treatments and a few ‘noncompliants’).Footnote 19 One can interpret the intention-to-treat as an evaluation of the overall treatment effects where the ‘treatment’ is having an option to sign an oath, compared to when it is mandatory and when there is no oath.

Table 1 reports the coefficient estimations from the linear probability regressions with robust standard errors clustered at the group level (since decisions are correlated at the group level due to group chat). The dependent variable is a binary indicator whether the participant lie in part 2 (1 if liar and 0 otherwise). Groups that observe in part 2 are excluded as they cannot lie upward (no one lies downward). The independent variables in model 1 include dummy variables for the oath treatments (Mand-Oath and Vol-Oath with No-Oath as a reference category), which take the value of 1 if the respective treatment is assigned and 0 otherwise, a dummy variable ‘PC,’ which takes the value of 1 if individuals face the payoff commonality rule and 0 otherwise, and their interaction terms. Model 2 further controls for socio-demographics (age, gender, and self-reported risk attitudes, field of study in business and economics, the number of tokens observed in the video in part 2 (ranging from 0 to 4 tokens), and individual types based on the decisions in part 1 (honest by choice or by observing ‘5’, with liar as a reference category).Footnote 20

Table 1. Treatment effects (Intention-to-treat)

*** Notes: p < 0.01 This table reports coefficient estimations from the linear probability models. Robust standard errors clustered at the group level in parentheses. The dependent variable is a binary indicator whether the participant lies in part 2 (coded one for liar, zero otherwise).

Model 1 includes dummy variables for the oath treatments (Mand-Oath and Vol-Oath, with No-Oath as a reference category), a dummy variable for payoff commonality treatment (‘PC’) and their interaction terms. Model 2 further controls for socio-demographics, namely age, gender (coded one for male, zero otherwise), self-reported risk attitudes, a dummy indicating a field of study in business and economics, the number of tokens observed in part 2, and dummy variables for individual types based on their decision in part 1 (honest by choice or by observing ‘5’, and liar as a reference category). Groups that observe in part 2 are excluded. This analysis does not include observations in the Mand-Oath Indiv treatment.

Does an oath reduce the likelihood to lie in groups? Results from Table 1 suggest that it does. Looking at model 1, when group members do not face payoff commonality, swearing a mandatory oath reduces lying in groups by about 18 percentage points compared to when there is no oath (p = 0.009). Strikingly, when oath-taking becomes voluntary (Vol-Oath vs. Mand-Oath), the likelihood to lie under no payoff commonality reduces by an additional 20 percentage points (p = 0.011, Wald test). A similar pattern is observed under payoff commonality. When group members face the payoff commonality rule, a mandatory oath reduces lying in groups by about 9 percentage points, but the effect remains insignificant (p = 0.244, Wald test). Nonetheless, making an oath voluntary reduces the likelihood to lie further by about 19 percentage points compared to mandating it. This effect is weakly significant under payoff commonality (p = 0.065, Wald test).

These results are robust to the inclusion of control variables (see model 2 in Table 1). A mandatory oath is effective under no payoff commonality (p = 0.005) and remains ineffective under payoff commonality (p = 0.356, Wald test). The impact of making oath voluntary is significant under both incentive structures (p = 0.016 for NPC treatments, and p = 0.050 for PC treatments, Wald tests).Footnote 21 For the control variables, self-reported risk taking and studying business and economics are positively correlated with the likelihood to lie in part 2 (significant at 1% and 5% level respectively). Observing a higher number of tokens and individual honest types are negatively associated with the likelihood to lie (all significant at 1% level).

In sum, the results in this section suggest that while an oath works in a group setting, its effectiveness depends on the incentive structures and the oath-taking procedure. A mandatory oath is effective when group members’ payoffs are independent. The impact of the mandatory oath becomes diluted once peer pressure is introduced through the payoff commonality rule. A voluntary procedure enhances the impact of an oath under both incentive structures, potentially by fostering an intrinsic motivation to uphold the promise to be honest.Footnote 22

4.2. Heterogeneous responses to the oath

This section examines individual heterogeneity in response to the treatments. How do different types of individuals react to the oath? For whom do procedures matter? Based on the individual decision in part 1, participants are classified as an honest type if they do not misreport the outcome of the die roll, and as a dishonest type if they do. This variable is crucial to control for self-selection bias when the oath is voluntary.Footnote 23

Table 2 presents the coefficient estimations from the linear probability regressions with robust standard errors clustered at the group level. The dependent variable is the dummy variable indicating whether the individual lie in part 2 or not. As in Table 1, Table 2 uses an intention-to-treat strategy and considers the same regression specifications, except that the regressions are performed separately for each individual type (models 1 and 2 for honest types, models 3 and 4 for dishonest types). Therefore, this analysis controls for self-selection by conditioning the treatment effects on a given level of preferences for truth-telling.

Table 2. Treatment effects conditional on type (Intention-to-treat)

** Notes: p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 This table reports coefficient estimations from the linear probability models separately for honest types (models 1 and 2) and dishonest types (models 3 and 4). Types are determined by the decision in part 1. Robust standard errors clustered at the group level in parentheses. The dependent variable is a binary indicator whether the participants lie in part 2 (coded one for liar, zero otherwise). Models 1 and 3 include dummy variables for the oath treatments (Mand-Oath and Vol-Oath, with No-Oath as a reference category), a dummy variable for payoff commonality treatment (‘PC’) and their interaction terms. Models 2 and 4 further controls for socio-demographics, namely age, gender (coded one for male, zero otherwise), self-reported risk attitudes, a dummy indicating a field of study in business and economics, and the number of tokens observed in part 2. For honest type, an additional dummy is included to control for individuals who are honest by observing ‘5’ in part 1. Groups that observe in part 2 are excluded. This analysis does not include observations in Mand-Oath Indiv treatment.

Overall, the results in Table 2 are consistent with those reported in Table 1 with one additional insight. While the oath affects both honest and dishonest types, the voluntary procedure strengthens the power of the oath solely for the honest types. Compared to honest individuals who do not take any oath, those who swear a mandatory oath under no payoff commonality reduce the likelihood to lie by about 24–26 percentage points (see models 1 and 2). The voluntary procedure further reduces the likelihood to lie by about 20 - 23 percentage points among this subset (p = 0.080, model 1 and p = 0.036 model 2, Wald tests). A similar result is observed under the payoff commonality rule. The impact of the mandatory oath under payoff commonality is limited even among the honest types (which is about 6 - 8 percentage points), while the voluntary procedure further reduces lying by about 20-26 percentage points for the honest types (p = 0.083 model 1 and p = 0.013 model 2, Wald tests).

Such enhancing effects of the voluntary procedure are not observed among the dishonest types (see models 3–4). For this subset of individuals, the reduction in the likelihood to lie caused by a mandatory oath under no payoff commonality is about 12–14 percentage points, but the voluntary procedure does not cause any additional reduction. This is also true under payoff commonality.Footnote 24

In sum, the results in this section indicate that the mandatory oath changes the behavior of both honest and dishonest types. Nonetheless, the voluntary procedure enhances the impact of the oath primarily among the honest subgroup.

4.3. Mechanisms

To better understand how an oath works in groups with social interactions, this section presents results from additional analyses that shed light on the mechanisms of contagion and peer pressure by looking at (i) how group members coordinate under oath, and (ii) how individuals behave post group interaction (behavior in part 3).Footnote 25 Groups that observe in part 2 are not included in the analysis. Wherever appropriate, comparisons are made with the control condition (Mand-Oath Indiv treatment) to help disentangle peer effects. All p-values reported in this section are from two-sided tests.

4.3.1. Contagion

Contagion operates in the experiment through group chat in part 2 where participants can learn what their peers will do (the empirical norm) as well as what others consider as an (in)appropriate thing to do (the injunctive norm). This allows individuals to internalize peers’ normative views, giving rise to contagion. To investigate this mechanism, the analyses in this section focus on the NPC treatments. Since group members can communicate and earn independent payoffs, behaviors in the NPC treatments cannot be driven by the group’s financial motive but rather by the erosion of social norms caused by communication. In addition, a comparison between Mand-Oath NPC and Mand-Oath Indiv makes a clear case for contagion in the former, as participants in the latter swore a mandatory oath and played the game individually without communicating with peers.

Table 3 presents the coordination rates by the nature of reports in the NPC treatments. In addition, the corresponding statistics in the Mand-Oath Indiv treatment are reported as a benchmark for no contagion.Footnote 26 Looking first at the group settings (i.e., NPC treatments), the pattern of coordination speaks to how an oath works in the presence of contagion. A mandatory oath in a group setting reduces dishonest coordination relative to no oath; from 81% in No-Oath NPC to 50% in Mand-Oath NPC (p = 0.017, exact test). Making oaths voluntary reduces dishonest coordination further to 23% in Vol-Oath NPC (p = 0.025, exact test). Though honest coordination increases in both oath treatments, the differences are not significant.Footnote 27 This implies that the introduction of an oath in settings with contagion causes the lying norm to break down, but it does not succeed in pushing all members to coordinate on the honesty norm.

Table 3. Coordination rates in the NPC treatments

Notes: This table reports the coordination rates in the NPC treatments, and the Mand-Oath Indiv treatment. Coordination rates are reported at the group level (coded as one if all members report the same number, zero otherwise). Coordination is reported as overall and separately for honest and dishonest reports. Note that two observations in the Mand-Oath Indiv treatment do not have groups, and are not included in this analysis. One of the 33 groups has two members.

To explore the extent to which contagion persists under oath, comparing the coordination rates in Mand-Oath NPC to those in Mand-Oath Indiv confirms that contagion erodes the honesty norm through communication. When individuals can communicate with peers, they become less inclined to coordinate on honest reports (30 percentage points, p = 0.005 exact test), and more so on dishonest reports (50 percentage points, p < 0.001 exact test). Taken together, these results suggest that group communication leads to a contagion of dishonesty, facilitating the erosion of norms. Without any group financial incentive, an oath curbs contagion by enhancing intrinsic motivation, which constrains individuals from following peer’s norm violation.

Additional support for contagion comes from analyzing the spillover effects of the group setting in part 2 on individual behavior in part 3. If individuals have learned from their peers of the weak injunctive and empirical norms via group chat, it is intuitive to anticipate that due to the erosion of norms, individuals are more likely to break the oath later, compared to those who are not exposed to any contagion. This can be directly tested by comparing the behaviors in part 3 of participants in the Mand-Oath NPC and Mand-Oath Indiv treatments. The analysis of spillover effect of contagion (reported in Table D7 in Online Appendix) confirms the intuition: mandatory oath-takers who do not interact with others are about 15 percentage points less likely to lie in part 3 compared to those who have interacted with others in part 2 (significant at 1% level). This is consistent with the presence of contagion of dishonesty in the group setting.Footnote 28

4.3.2. Peer pressure

In this experiment, peer pressure is a byproduct of the payoff commonality rule because an individual’s decision has collective consequences for the group. The rule requires group members to coordinate to earn a common payoff, otherwise they earn nothing. Assuming that the group does not observe a payoff maximizing outcome (i.e., ‘5’), based on rationality alone, each individual misreports to maximize group’s payoff. Heterogeneity in preferences can lead members to interpret the norms differently and consequently prefer to take different courses of actions.

Introducing an oath makes the honesty norm more salient.Footnote 29 Depending on which norm emerges as the majority opinion, an individual may become a ‘weak link’ and be pressured to report either the truth (if honesty is the group norm) or ‘5’ (if payoff maximization is the group norm).Footnote 30 In this setting, peer pressure prevents individuals from deviating from the group norm because doing so is financially costly for the group and socially costly for the deviator.

Table 4 reports the coordination rates in the PC treatments. The fact that only 6% of groups in No-Oath PC coordinate on the honest reports, while 94% coordinate on dishonest reports suggests that profit maximization is the predominant norm in the absence of an oath. A mandatory oath causes about 10% of the groups to switch from dishonest to honest coordination, but the differences remain insignificant when comparing No-Oath PC and Mand-Oath PC (p = 0.426, exact tests). These rates change when the oath becomes voluntary. Compared to No-Oath PC and Mand-Oath PC, groups in Vol-Oath PC are more likely to coordinate on honest reports and less likely to coordinate on dishonest reports. The shifts in coordination rates from No-Oath PC to Vol-Oath PC are significant for both honest (p = 0.024, exact test) and dishonest coordination (p = 0.001, exact test).Footnote 31 Taken together, the pattern in group coordination suggests that while a mandatory oath makes the honesty norm salient and has some effects on behavior, it may not be strong enough to overcome peer pressure to lie. As a result, the mandatory oath is unable to shift the group norm from payoff maximization to one of honesty. However, voluntary oath-taking facilitates honesty to emerge as a group norm because of a stronger intrinsic motivation to commit more firmly to the promise one has made. This is reflected in some levels of miscoordination when an oath is voluntary, suggesting that some individuals are not willing to break the voluntary oath.

Table 4. Coordination rates in the PC treatments

Notes: This table reports the coordination rates in the PC treatments. Coordination rates are reported at the group level (coded as one if all members report the same number, zero otherwise). Coordination is reported as overall and separately for honest and dishonest reports.

The analysis of the spillover effects of the group setting in part 2 on the behaviors in part 3 also lends support to peer pressure under the payoff commonality rule. If individuals have lied due to peer pressure, how will they behave later compared to those who have lied due to contagion? Unlike contagion where individuals internalize peers’ normative views, those who lie out of peer pressure do so to avoid the social costs of deviating from the group norm, without necessarily adopting their peers’ views. As such, the likelihood to lie in part 3 among those who have lied in part 2 due to peer pressure (i.e., PC treatments) is expected to be lower compared to those who have lied in part 2 because they learned from others that lying is acceptable (i.e., NPC treatments).Footnote 32

The analysis of the spillover effects of peer pressure (reported in Table D8 in Online Appendix) shows that compared to those who lie in part 2 in NPC treatments, individuals who lie in part 2 in PC treatments are less likely to lie in part 3. This effect persists in both oath treatments and is stronger.Footnote 33 This suggests that people who lie to live up to peers’ expectations are less likely to lie later compared to those who lie because they have internalized the normative views of their peers. This is consistent with peer pressure under the payoff commonality rule.

5. Discussion and Conclusion

This study demonstrates that an oath can be effective in group settings but its impact varies depending on the incentive structures and oath-taking procedures. When payoffs are determined individually, a mandatory oath significantly limits the contagion of dishonesty. However, its impact becomes marginal when payoffs are determined collectively. This can be explained by how peer pressure erodes the honesty norm in favor of profit maximization. Making the oath voluntary fosters intrinsic motivation, which enhances the oath’s effectiveness under both incentive structures. These results highlight the importance of social interactions in determining the effectiveness of an oath in groups.

Why does the impact of the mandatory oath in groups depend on the incentive structures, but the effect of voluntary procedure remains stable across both incentive structures? The mechanism of peer pressure explains this. Depending on what the group norm is, peer pressure deters individuals from deviating from the majority opinion. Additional analyses suggest that while the honesty norm indeed becomes salient under a mandatory oath, it struggles to emerge as a group norm, leading peer pressure to erode the oath’s effectiveness. However, when the oath becomes voluntary, the honesty norm is able to catch up with the profit maximization norm. This is consistent with a stronger intrinsic motivation under the voluntary oath, shifting peer pressure in favor of the honesty norm.

While one should remain cautious of the generalizability of lab findings, these results could be relevant in an organizational context where oaths are implemented, and where peer effects are naturally present. The experiment shows that an oath can serve as a psychological contract to morally engage individuals, constraining them from following peers’ norm violation. The oath therefore can play an important role in counteracting the erosion of norms in settings prone to the contagion of dishonesty. The role of peer pressure is more nuanced. To make an oath impactful in group settings, honesty must emerge as the predominant norm. This is particularly important in situations where the deviation from the group norm entails social costs for individuals, and financial costs for the group. To achieve this end, leveraging individual intrinsic motivation to uphold the promise can facilitate the emergence of honesty norm.

This study opens up new research avenues. Future work can focus on finding the ways to sustain the impact of an oath in groups, which is found to be short-lived in the current setting. This is in contrast to other studies in individual settings, which demonstrated a long-lasting impact of an oath (Peer & Feldman, Reference Peer and Feldman2021, Kingsuwankul et al., Reference Kingsuwankul, Tergiman and Villeval2023). Quantifying the extent of norms erosion, and identifying how to counter and reverse the decay can be useful in designing oath interventions. In relation to the oath-taking procedures, a better understanding of the role of beliefs can be useful in identifying the extent to which the impact of voluntary oath-taking relates to one’s belief about others’ decision to sign the oath and thus the honesty norm in general. Another direction will be to dig deeper into the different motives that drive voluntary oath-taking. Saccardo and Serra-Garcia Reference Saccardo and Serra-Garcia(2023) show that 30% of individuals willingly seek out information to constrain their future selves from self-serving behavior. Future works could identify and separate different motivations behind voluntary oath-taking (e.g., intrinsic vs. instrumental), which may help in tailoring interventions to appeal to specific groups of individuals and enhance their impact.

Acknowledgements

Earlier versions of this paper circulated under the title “Individual oath-swearing and lying under peer pressure” and “Oath, autonomy and lying in groups”. The author is grateful to the two co-editors and the two reviewers, B. Corgnet, L. Gangadharan, N. Jacquemet, C. Rott, V. Valero, M. C. and Villeval, A. Zylbersztejn for their valuable feedback. The author thanks participants at the Winter School on Credence Goods, Incentives and Behavior in Innsbruck, ASFEE in Lyon, the Experimental Seminar at SBE VU, the Market, Cooperation and Voting Workshop in Madrid, and ESA Meeting in Helsinki for their useful comments. The author also thanks Q. Thevenet, C. Sénichault, B. Monjour, and A. Thampi for their assistance. This research has benefited from the financial support of IDEXLYON from Université de Lyon (INDEPTH-IDEX/SBP/2018/03) within the Programme Investissements d’Avenir (ANR-16-IDEX-0005) operated by the French National Research Agency, the funding program of GATE-LAB Lyon, and the Department of Management and Organization, SBE VU Amsterdam. This research also benefited from the support of the LABEX CORTEX (ANR-11-LABX-0042) of the Université de Lyon, within the Programme Investissements d’Avenir (ANR-11-IDEX-007) operated by the French National Research Agency (ANR). The replication and supplementary material for the study is available at https://doi.org/10.17605/OSF.IO/D8QAH

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/eec.2025.10018.

Footnotes

1 This notion aligns with that of Kandel and Lazear Reference Kandel and Lazear(1992) who conceptualizes peer pressure as non-pecuniary social costs that deter agents from shirking in partnerships and teams.

2 A real-world example is the bankers’ oath, which aims to morally engage financial advisors. The Netherlands made this professional oath compulsory for all bankers since 2015, while Australia recently implemented a similar oath but made it voluntary. For information about the bankers’ oath, see https://www.tuchtrechtbanken.nl/en/about-the-bankers-oath/ for the Netherlands and https://www.bfso.org/the-oath/mission-and-objectives for Australia (accessed on 20th December 2024).

3 Naturally, the voluntary procedure introduces endogeneity. By using individual decisions in part 1 as a proxy for their type, important aspects of the self-selection effect can be controlled for.

4 A meta-analysis by Zickfeld et al. Reference Zickfeld, Karg, Engen, Gonzalez, Michael and Mitkidis(2024) reported an overall negative impact of an oath on lying. Recent studies show that the effect of an oath may depend on the context. An oath can have a limited impact on partial lies compared to obvious ones (Heinicke et al., Reference Heinicke, Rosenkranz and Weitzel2019, Jacquemet et al., Reference Jacquemet, James, Luchini, Murphy and Shogren2021), and on lies that are mutually beneficial compared to self-serving ones (Jacquemet et al., Reference Jacquemet, Luchini, Rosaz and Shogren2021). Some studies reported no effects (Koessler et al., Reference Koessler, Torgler, Feld and Frey2019, Prima et al., Reference Prima, Feeny, Hoffmann and Satriawan2020, Cagala et al., Reference Cagala, Glogowsky, Rincke and Schudy2023) or even backfiring (Cagala et al., Reference Cagala, Glogowsky and Rincke2021).

5 Other well-documented mechanisms in explaining the high prevalence of lying (or norm violation more generally) in a group context are rationality (Charness & Sutter, Reference Charness and Sutter2012), sophisticated deception (Sutter, Reference Sutter2009), diffusion of responsibility (e.g., Falk & Szech, Reference Falk and Szech2013, Falk et al., Reference Falk, Neuber and Szech2020, Bauer et al., Reference Bauer, Cahlikova, Katreniak, Chytilova, Cingl and Zelinsky2023), Pareto white lies (e.g., Wiltermuth, Reference Wiltermuth2011, Conrads et al., Reference Conrads, Irlenbusch, Rilke and Walkowitz2013), and a lenient normative view (Behnk et al., Reference Behnk, Hao and Reuben2022).

6 Similar results have been documented in various settings such as tax evasion (Lefebvre et al., Reference Lefebvre, Pestieau, Riedl and Villeval2015, Burgstaller & Pfeil, Reference Burgstaller and Pfeil2024), the die-under-a-cup paradigm (Colzani et al., Reference Colzani, Michailidou and Santos-Pinto2023, Huber et al., Reference Huber, Litsios, Nieper and Promann2023) and deception game (Innes & Mitra, Reference Innes and Mitra2013).

7 Kandel and Lazear Reference Kandel and Lazear(1992) also models peer pressure as guilt aversion (as in Battigalli et al., Reference Battigalli, Charness and Dufwenberg2013), whereby an individual avoids an action that will fall below the group’s expectation.

8 Prior studies showed that individuals positively value decision rights (Fehr et al., Reference Fehr, Herz and Wilkening2013, Bartling et al., Reference Bartling, Fehr and Herz2014), prefer autonomy (i.e., the ability to implement one’s decision) (Ferreira et al., Reference Ferreira, Hanaki and Tarroux2020, Freundt et al., Reference Freundt, Herz and Kopp2023). and non-interference (i.e., independence from the decisions of others) (Pikulina & Tergiman, Reference Pikulina and Tergiman2020).

9 Given a high prevalence of lying observed in Kocher et al. Reference Kocher, Schudy and Spantig(2018), the set-up is well-suited as the results likely reflect situations where lying is a group norm. Key design features, such as group coordination, communication, group composition, and behavior after group interaction, can be helpful in understanding how an oath works in groups. Naturally, this replicates the group treatments of Kocher et al. Reference Kocher, Schudy and Spantig(2018), whose findings are confirmed (see section C.6 in Online Appendix for the replication of their main findings).

10 The program checked whether the following words were typed correctly: ‘I swear upon my honor,’ ‘honestly’ and ‘truth.’

11 Given the voluntary procedure, participants in the Vol-Oath treatment did not know who else signed the oath and could form beliefs regarding the decisions of others. In this respect, the set-up is similar to prior studies (see Jacquemet et al., Reference Jacquemet, Luchini, Rosaz and Shogren2019) who administered a voluntary oath where participants were not informed of others’ decisions. On the contrary, those in the Mand-Oath treatment did not have to form beliefs, and knew that others had also signed the oath. While the aim is to compare the effectiveness of oaths by varying the procedures, it can be interesting for future research to examine the extent to which beliefs about others signing the voluntary oath may matter.

12 The sentence was ‘I do not agree to take the oath and I understand that I can still continue to participate in the experiment.’ This was not common-knowledge. The procedure was adopted to avoid placing participants in an uncomfortable situation where their neighbors could infer something about their decision. The set-up also helps in reducing the salience of participants inferring how many participants in the session agreed or disagreed to take the oath.

13 The number of observations is based on an ex-ante power calculation (see the pre-registration #79968). The actual number of observations is slightly higher to account for instances where participants saw a video of in part 2 and could not engage in self-serving lies. See Table D1 in Online Appendix for an overview of the treatments and the number of observations.

14 Two participants in the Mand-Oath Indiv treatment experienced a technical issue where the videos of the die roll were not displayed and therefore not included in the final dataset.

15 Due to different turn-up rates across sessions, the videos shown were not perfectly balanced. To alleviate this issue, the program was made to allow a selection of specific videos from the first two sessions (e.g., in order to ‘catch up’ with the previous session). Table D5 in Online Appendix shows that the distributions of the videos displayed did not differ across treatments. The results are thus free from any differences in the videos shown.

16 For the sessions conducted in 2021, the project benefited from two sources of funding. Due to administrative issues, one was paid by bank transfer, while the other in cash. The author balanced the mode of payment across treatments. Regression analysis of these sessions shows no effect of cash payment on lying behavior (results available upon request).

17 In the context of the observed cheating game (Gneezy et al., Reference Gneezy, Kajackaite and Sobel2018), it is typical to analyze the decision to lie (i.e., the extensive margin) as those who decide to lie usually do so to the full extent (i.e., the intensive margin). This is observed in the experiment: among those who decide to lie, about 96%, 99%, and 99% lie to the full extent by reporting ‘5’ in part 1, 2, and 3 respectively. Therefore, the main analysis focuses on the treatment effects at the extensive margin.

18 There is no significant difference in the fractions of oath-takers in Vol-Oath NPC and Vol-Oath PC (73.33% and 68.63% respectively, p = 0.540, two-sided exact test). In addition, individuals who do not lie in part 1 are more likely to sign the oath when it is voluntary, suggesting self-selection (see Table D6 in Online Appendix). The analysis in section 4.2 controls for the important part of self-selection using the decision in part 1 as a proxy for individual type.

19 Checking the text of the oath after the experiment, all typed correctly with only minor errors that did not change the meaning of the oath, except for three (one each in Mand-Oath NPC, Vol-Oath PC and Mand-Oath Indiv). These three participants modified the meaning of the oath (e.g., ‘I will not be honest.’, ‘I will be honest, may be.’). This behavior can be considered as non-compliance. As the analysis uses an intention-to-treat strategy, these observations and their groups (if any) are not excluded.

20 Tables D2 and D3 in Online Appendix show that the characteristics of the samples are not perfectly balanced. In particular, the fraction of individual type (proxied by the decision in part 1) varies across some treatments. While the fraction of liars in part 1 ranges between 48% and 52% in the No-Oath and Mand-Oath treatments, it ranges between 30% and 32% in the Vol-Oath treatments, which are statistically lower. Thus, controlling for participants’ socio-demographics and types ensures that the treatment effects are not confounded.

21 The insignificance of ‘Mand-Oath X PC’ suggests no differences in the impact the mandatory oath under both incentive structures (p = 0.411 in model 1 and p = 0.232 in model 2). The effect of making oath voluntary is also similar under both incentive structures. The diff-in-diff post-estimations using Wald tests (i.e., the difference between Vol-Oath and Mand-Oath in the NPC treatment vs. in the PC treatment) return the following p-values: p = 0.880 (model 1) and p = 0.968 (model 2).

22 Online Appendix C.1 provides an additional analysis of the treatment effects at the intensive margin, which shows that the oath has no impact on the size of lies. This implies that in the current setting, the oath affects only the consideration to lie; once individuals have decided to lie, they do so to the full extent, irrespective of the oath.

23 This approach is limited by the ability to observe relevant characteristics that drive the decision to sign the oath and hinges on the assumption that the decision to lie in part 1 is informative of individual type. However, some prior studies documented a positive correlation between cheating in the lab and in the field (e.g., Potters & Stoop, Reference Potters and Stoop2016, Dai et al., Reference Dai, Galeotti and Villeval2017, Cohn & Maréchal, Reference Cohn and Maréchal2018), suggesting that such decisions can serve as proxies for individual types, though not without their limitations.

24 All post-estimations using Wald tests confirm no effect of the voluntary procedure for the dishonest types. The differences are insignificant for the NPC treatment: p = 0.825 (model 3) and p = 0.804 (model 4). The respective p-values for the PC treatment are p = 0.289 and p = 0.294.

25 Other aspects of the data also shed light on the peer effects mechanisms, namely belief, group composition, and chat. The analyses and related discussion can be found in Online Appendix C. The author would like to thank the two co-editors and the two reviewers who encouraged the use of these different aspects to better understand these mechanisms.

26 The only difference between Mand-Oath NPC and Mand-Oath Indiv is that in the latter participants play the game individually without communication. For this treatment, a ‘group’ refers to instances where the programme showed matched participants the same video of a die roll, but there was no communication by design. Two participants in Mand-Oath Indiv do not have any ‘groups’ and are not included in this analysis.

27 Pairwise comparisons using exact tests show insignificant differences. The smallest p-value is 0.108.

28 Other additional analyses support the mechanism of contagion. The chat analysis shows that the majority of groups use arguments in favor of lying at least once, which likely erodes the social norm in the group setting. The group composition analysis suggests that in treatments with communication, individuals condition, own lying decision on that of their group members. Belief data suggests that on average, participants in treatments with communication believe that the lying rate will be higher in part 3 compared to part 1. These additional analyses and related discussion can be found in Online Appendix C.

29 The injunctive norms were elicited in the Vol-Oath NPC, Vol-Oath PC and Mand-Oath Indiv treatments. It is shown that an oath changes social perceptions about the (in)appropriateness of lying in groups, where oath breaking is perceived as very inappropriate in all treatments. Although this is not a direct evidence for the Mand-Oath treatments, a similar shift could be expected. See Online Appendix C.5 for the discussion related to social norms.

30 Although various group norms may exist, the simplification of two competing norms is corroborated by the chat analysis. Conversations are mostly centered around profit maximization and morality (i.e., honesty as a value and respecting the oath). See Online Appendix C.4 for discussion on the content of communication.

31 Since the coordination rates in Mand-Oath PC fall between those of No-Oath PC and Vol-Oath PC, the difference between Mand-Oath PC and Vol-Oath PC is not significant for honest coordination (p = 0.244, exact test), but is significant for dishonest coordination (p = 0.030, exact test).

32 This intuition is in line with the literature on moral balancing (see Monin & Miller, Reference Monin and Miller2001, Ploner & Regner, Reference Ploner and Regner2013, Rahwan et al., Reference Rahwan, Hauser, Kochanowska and Fasolo2018), which theorizes that people maintain a balance of good and bad behaviors. Those who lie out of pressure may compensate for their past norm violation by behaving honestly later.

33 The spillover effect of pressure is true for No-Oath (model 1, p = 0.078, model 2, p = 0.049). Post-estimations using Wald tests reveal significant differences for both Mand-Oath (model 1, p = 0.012, model 2, p = 0.010) and Vol-Oath (both models, p < 0.001).

References

Abeler, J., Nosenzo, D., & Raymond, C. (2019). Preferences for truth-telling. Econometrica, 87(4), 11151153.10.3982/ECTA14673CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäker, A., & Mechtel, M. (2019). The impact of peer presence on cheating. Economic Inquiry, 57(2), 792812.10.1111/ecin.12760CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartling, B., Fehr, E., & Herz, H. (2014). The intrinsic value of decision rights. Econometrica, 82(6), 20052039.10.3982/ECTA11573CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battigalli, P., Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2013). Deception: The role of guilt. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 93, 227232.10.1016/j.jebo.2013.03.033CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauer, M., Cahlikova, J., Katreniak, D. C., Chytilova, J., Cingl, L., & Zelinsky, T. (2023). Nastiness in groups. Journal of the European Economic Association, (jvad072), 133.Google Scholar
Beck, T. (2021). How the honesty oath works: Quick, intuitive truth telling under oath. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 94, .10.1016/j.socec.2021.101728CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Behnk, S., Hao, L., & Reuben, E. (2022). Shifting normative beliefs: On why groups behave more antisocially than individuals. European Economic Review, 145, .10.1016/j.euroecorev.2022.104116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, C., Dimant, E., & Sonderegger, S. (2023). It’s not a lie if you believe the norm does not apply: Conditional norm-following and belief distortion. Games and Economic Behavior, 138, 321354.10.1016/j.geb.2023.01.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bock, O., Baetge, I., & Nicklisch, A. (2014). hroot: Hamburg Registration and Organization Online Tool. European Economic Review, 71, 117120.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2014.07.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burgstaller, L., & Pfeil, K. (2024). You don’t need an invoice, do you? An online experiment on collaborative tax evasion. Journal of Economic Psychology, 101, .10.1016/j.joep.2024.102708CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cagala, T., Glogowsky, U., & Rincke, J. (2021). Detecting and preventing cheating in exams: Evidence from a field experiment. Journal of Human Resources, 59(1), .Google Scholar
Cagala, T., Glogowsky, U., Rincke, J., & Schudy, S. (2023). Commitment requests do not affect truth-telling in laboratory and online experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 143(202401), 179190.10.1016/j.geb.2023.11.014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74(6), 15791601.10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00719.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Sutter, M. (2012). Groups make better self-interested decisions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(3), 157176.10.1257/jep.26.3.157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charroin, L., Fortin, B., & Villeval, M. C. (2022). Peer effects, self-selection and dishonesty. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 200, 618637.10.1016/j.jebo.2022.06.024CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohn, A., & Maréchal, M. A. (2018). Laboratory measure of cheating predicts school misconduct. The Economic Journal, 128(615), 27432754.10.1111/ecoj.12572CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colzani, P., Michailidou, G., & Santos-Pinto, L. (2023). Experimental evidence on the transmission of honesty and dishonesty: A stairway to heaven and a highway to hell. Economics Letters, 231, .10.1016/j.econlet.2023.111257CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conrads, J., Irlenbusch, B., Rilke, R. M., & Walkowitz, G. (2013). Lying and team incentives. Journal of Economic Psychology, 34, 17.10.1016/j.joep.2012.10.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dai, Z., Galeotti, F., & Villeval, M. C. (2017). Cheating in the lab predicts fraud in the field: An experiment in public transportation. Management Science, 64(3), 10811100.10.1287/mnsc.2016.2616CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, B. J., & Jaber-Lopez, T. (2022). Do voluntary commitment mechanisms improve welfare? The effect of mandatory and voluntary oaths in a social dilemma. Bulletin of Economic Research, 75(2), 525540.10.1111/boer.12369CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A., Przepiorka, W., & Rauhut, H. (2015). Lifting the veil of ignorance: An experiment on the contagiousness of norm violations. Rationality and Society, 27(3), 309333.10.1177/1043463115593109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimant, E., Galeotti, F., & Villeval, M. C. (2024). Motivated information acquisition and social norm formation. European Economic Review, 167, .10.1016/j.euroecorev.2024.104778CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., & Dufwenberg, M. A. (2018). Lies in disguise – a theoretical analysis of cheating. Journal of Economic Theory, 175, 248264.10.1016/j.jet.2018.01.013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunaiev, Y., & Khadjavi, M. (2021). Collective Honesty? Experimental evidence on the effectiveness of honesty nudging for teams. Frontiers in Psychology, 12, 18.10.3389/fpsyg.2021.684755CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ellingsen, T., & Johannesson, M. (2004). Promises, threats and fairness. The Economic Journal, 114(495), 397420.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2004.00214.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., Neuber, T., & Szech, N. (2020). Diffusion of being pivotal and immoral outcomes. The Review of Economic Studies, 87(5), 22052229.10.1093/restud/rdz064CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., & Szech, N. (2013). Morals and markets. Science, 340(6133), 707711.10.1126/science.1231566CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fehr, E., Herz, H., & Wilkening, T. (2013). The lure of authority: Motivation and incentive effects of power. American Economic Review, 103(4), 13251359.10.1257/aer.103.4.1325CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferreira, J. V., Hanaki, N., & Tarroux, B. (2020). On the roots of the intrinsic value of decision rights: Experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 119, 110122.10.1016/j.geb.2019.10.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178.10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fosgaard, T. R., Hansen, L. G., & Piovesan, M. (2013). Separating will from grace: An experiment on conformity and awareness in cheating. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 93, 279284.10.1016/j.jebo.2013.03.027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freundt, J., Herz, H., and Kopp, L. (2023). Intrinsic preferences for choice autonomy. CESifo Working PaperGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U., Kajackaite, A., & Sobel, J. (2018). Lying aversion and the size of the lie. American Economic Review, 108(2), 419453.10.1257/aer.20161553CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, J., Leib, M., Offerman, T., & Shalvi, S. (2018). Ethical free riding: When honest people find dishonest partners. Psychological Science, 29(12), 19561968.10.1177/0956797618796480CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Heinicke, F., Rosenkranz, S., & Weitzel, U. (2019). The effect of pledges on the distribution of lying behavior: An online experiment. Journal of Economic Psychology, 73, 136151.10.1016/j.joep.2019.05.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, C., Litsios, C., Nieper, A., & Promann, T. (2023). On social norms and observability in (dis)honest behavior. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 212, 10861099.10.1016/j.jebo.2023.06.019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Innes, R., & Mitra, A. (2013). Is dishonesty contagious?. Economic Inquiry, 51(1), 722734.Google Scholar
Jacquemet, N., James, A., Luchini, S., Murphy, J., & Shogren, J. (2021). Do truth-telling oaths improve honesty in crowd-working?. PLoS ONE, 16, 426438.Google ScholarPubMed
Jacquemet, N., Luchini, S., Rosaz, J., & Shogren, J. F. (2019). Truth telling under oath. Management Science, 65(1), 426438.10.1287/mnsc.2017.2892CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacquemet, N., Luchini, S., Rosaz, J., & Shogren, J. F. (2021). Can we commit future managers to honesty?. Frontiers in Psychology, 12(2785), 18.10.3389/fpsyg.2021.701627CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kandel, E., & Lazear, E. P. (1992). Peer pressure and partnerships. Journal of Political Economy, 100(4), 801817.10.1086/261840CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keizer, K., Lindenberg, S., & Steg, L. (2008). The spreading of disorder. Science, 322(5908), 16811685.10.1126/science.1161405CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kingsuwankul, S., Tergiman, C., and Villeval, M. C. (2023). Why do oaths work? Image concerns and credibility in promise keeping. SSRN.10.2139/ssrn.4574459CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kocher, M. G., Schudy, S., & Spantig, L. (2018). I lie? We lie! Why? Experimental evidence on a dishonesty shift in groups. Management Science, 64(9), 39954008.10.1287/mnsc.2017.2800CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koessler, A. -K., Torgler, B., Feld, L. P., & Frey, B. S. (2019). Commitment to pay taxes: Results from field and laboratory experiments. European Economic Review, 115, 7898.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2019.02.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kroher, M., & Wolbring, T. (2015). Social control, social learning, and cheating: Evidence from lab and online experiments on dishonesty. Social Science Research, 53, 311324.10.1016/j.ssresearch.2015.06.003CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Krupka, E. L., & Weber, R. A. (2013). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary?. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 495524.10.1111/jeea.12006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lauer, T., and Untertrifaller, A. (2019). Conditional dishonesty. mimeoGoogle Scholar
Lefebvre, M., Pestieau, P., Riedl, A., & Villeval, M. C. (2015). Tax evasion and social information: An experiment in Belgium, France, and the Netherlands. International Tax and Public Finance, 22(3), 401425.10.1007/s10797-014-9318-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Monin, B., & Miller, D. T. (2001). Moral credentials and the expression of prejudice. Journal of Personality and Social psychology, 81(1), .10.1037/0022-3514.81.1.33CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Peer, E., & Feldman, Y. (2021). Honesty pledges for the behaviorally-based regulation of dishonesty. Journal of European Public Policy, 28(10), 121.10.1080/13501763.2021.1912149CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pikulina, E., & Tergiman, C. (2020) Preferences for non-interference in pay. SSRN.10.2139/ssrn.3515050CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ploner, M., & Regner, T. (2013). Self-image and moral balancing: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 93, 374383.10.1016/j.jebo.2013.03.030CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potters, J., & Stoop, J. (2016). Do cheaters in the lab also cheat in the field?. European Economic Review, 87, 2633.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2016.03.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prima, R. A., Feeny, S., Hoffmann, R., Satriawan, E. (2020). Threats, pledges, and asset misreporting: A Framed field experiment in Indonesia. Technical report, RMIT University, Australia.Google Scholar
Rahwan, Z., Hauser, O. P., Kochanowska, E., & Fasolo, B. (2018). High stakes: A little more cheating, a lot less charity. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 152, 276295.10.1016/j.jebo.2018.04.021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saccardo, S., & Serra-Garcia, M. (2023). Enabling or limiting cognitive flexibility? Evidence of demand for moral commitment. American Economic Review, 113(2), 396429.10.1257/aer.20201333CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schudy, S., Grundmann, S., & Spantig, L. (2024). Individual Preferences for Truth-Telling SSRN.Google Scholar
Sutter, M. (2009). Deception through telling the truth?! Experimental evidence from individuals and teams. The Economic Journal, 119(534), 4760.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2008.02205.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanberg, C. (2008). Why do people keep their promises? An Experimental test of two explanations. Econometrica, 76(6), 14671480.Google Scholar
Weisel, O., & Shalvi, S. (2015). The collaborative roots of corruption. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112, 1065110656.10.1073/pnas.1423035112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiltermuth, S. S. (2011). Cheating more when the spoils are split. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 115(2), 157168.10.1016/j.obhdp.2010.10.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zickfeld, J., Karg, S. T., Engen, S. S., Gonzalez, A. S. R., Michael, J., & Mitkidis, P. (2024). Committed (Dis)Honesty: A Systematic Meta-Analytic Review of the Divergent Effects of Social Commitment to Individuals or Honesty Oaths on Dishonest Behavior. Psychological Bulletin, 150(5), .10.1037/bul0000429CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zickfeld, J., Ścigała, K. A., Weiss, A., Michael, J., & Mitkidis, P. (2023). Commitment to honesty oaths decreases dishonesty, but commitment to another individual does not affect dishonesty. Communications Psychology, 1(1), .10.1038/s44271-023-00028-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Treatment effects (Intention-to-treat)

Figure 1

Table 2. Treatment effects conditional on type (Intention-to-treat)

Figure 2

Table 3. Coordination rates in the NPC treatments

Figure 3

Table 4. Coordination rates in the PC treatments

Supplementary material: File

Kingsuwankul supplementary material

Kingsuwankul supplementary material
Download Kingsuwankul supplementary material(File)
File 85.2 KB