Hostname: page-component-54dcc4c588-sdd8f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-10-13T23:51:23.921Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Agency and the Pace of Adoption of NewTechniques

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Ronald W. Anderson
Affiliation:
London School of Economics and Political Science and IRES Université catholique de Louvain
Kjell G. Nyborg
Affiliation:
London Business School and CEPR
Get access

Summary

We study the relation of financial contracting and the pace of technologicaladvance in a dynamic agency theoretic model. A firm which is financed byoutside shareholders but run by managers has the prospect of a processinnovation which arrives stochastically. Adopting the innovation requiresfiring old management and hiring new with skills appropriate for the newtechnique. We show that subgame perfect equilibria in this game can be oftwo types. In “entrenchment” equilibrium once the new technique has beenannounced old style management raises their dividend payout sufficiently topreempt the innovation. In “maximum rent extraction” equilibrium’ managersare unable or unwilling to match the impending productivity improvement andinstead respond by increasing their perquisites for the remaining time oftheir tenure. We show that both equilibria involve several types ofinefficiencies and can result in underinvestment in positive NPV projects.We discuss the role of financial innovation in reducing the inefficienciesidentified.

Résumé

Résumé

Nous étudions la relation entre le contrat financier et le rythme del’avance technologique dans un modèle théorique dynamique de l’agence. Unefirme, financée par des actionnaires externes mais gérée par descadres-dirigeants, a la possibilité de connaître un processus d’innovationqui survient de façon stochastique. L’adoption d’une innovation nécessite delicencier les dirigeants et d’en embaucher de nouveaux ayant lesqualifications en adéquation avec la nouvelle technique. Nous montrons que,dans ce jeu, les équilibres parfaits de sous-jeux peuvent être de deuxtypes: à l’équilibre « blocage », une fois que la nouvelle technique a étéannoncée, les dirigeants en place augmentent le dividende payé de manière àempêcher l’innovation d’être mise en oeuvre. À l’équilibre « extractionmaximale de la rente » les dirigeants sous menace de licenciement réagissenten augmentant leurs privilèges jusqu’à la fin de leurs fonctions dansl’organisation. Nous montrons que les deux équilibres comportent plusieurstypes d’inefficiences et qu’ils peuvent aboutir à un sous-investissementdans les projets à valeur actuelle nette positive. Nous discutons, pourfinir, du rôle que peut avoir l’innovation financière afin de reduire cesinefficiences.

Information

Type
III. Finance
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2002 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

Footnotes

*

We have benefitted from comments of participants of the “New Economy : Implications and Viability” conference at the University of Metz, April 2001. Responsibility for all errors and views expressed is our own. This research has been supported by the Belgian French Community,Action de Recherche Concertée, 99/04-235. Anderson :r.w.anderson@lse.ac.uk and Nyborg : knyborg@london.edu

References

Anderson, R.W. and Nyborg, K.G. (2001a) “Financing and Corporate Growth under Repeated Moral Hazard” Working Paper No.376, London School of Economics, Financial Markets Group.Google Scholar
Anderson, R.W. and Nyborg, K.G., (2001b) “Financial Development, Agency and the Pace of Adoption of New Techniques”, Working Paper No.389, London School of Economics, Financial Markets Group.Google Scholar
Aghion, P. and Bolton, P. (1992), “Distribution and Growth in Models of Imperfect Capital Markets”, The European Economic Review, 36, 603611.Google Scholar
Banerjee, A. and Newman, A. (1991), “Risk-bearing and the Theory of Income Distribution”, Review of Economic Studies, 58, 211235.Google Scholar
Berle, A.A. and Means, G.C. (1932), The Modern Corporation and Private Property MacMillan Publishing Co., New York.Google Scholar
Gershenkron, A. (1962), Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Goldsmith, R. (1969), Financial Structure and Development, Yale U. P.Google Scholar
Greenwood, J. and Jovanovic, B. (1990), “FinancialDevelopment, Growth and the Distribution of Income”, Journal of Political Economy, 98, 10761107.Google Scholar
Hart, O. (1996), Contracts and Corporate Financial Structure and Development, Oxford U. P.Google Scholar
Hobijn, B. and Jovanovic, B. (1999), “The Information Technology Revolution and the Stock Market”, working paper, New York University.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. and Meckling, W., 1976, “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Capital Structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, 305–60.Google Scholar
King, R.G. and Levine, R. (1993), “Financial Intermediation and Economic Development,” Mayer, C. and Vives, X. (eds.), Capital Markets and Financial Intermediation, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kiyotaki, N. and Moore, J. (1997), “Credit Cycles”, Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), 211–48.Google Scholar
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. Shleifer, A. Vishny, R.W. (1998), “Law and Finance”, Journal of Political Economy, 106, 11131155.Google Scholar
Rajan, R.G. and Zingales, L. (1998), “Financial Dependence and Growth”, American Economic Review, 88, 559–86.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar