Hostname: page-component-6bb9c88b65-9rk55 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-07-23T22:27:03.690Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 September 2014

Abstract

Each of four theoretical traditions in the study of American politics—which can be characterized as theories of Majoritarian Electoral Democracy, Economic-Elite Domination, and two types of interest-group pluralism, Majoritarian Pluralism and Biased Pluralism—offers different predictions about which sets of actors have how much influence over public policy: average citizens; economic elites; and organized interest groups, mass-based or business-oriented.

A great deal of empirical research speaks to the policy influence of one or another set of actors, but until recently it has not been possible to test these contrasting theoretical predictions against each other within a single statistical model. We report on an effort to do so, using a unique data set that includes measures of the key variables for 1,779 policy issues.

Multivariate analysis indicates that economic elites and organized groups representing business interests have substantial independent impacts on U.S. government policy, while average citizens and mass-based interest groups have little or no independent influence. The results provide substantial support for theories of Economic-Elite Domination and for theories of Biased Pluralism, but not for theories of Majoritarian Electoral Democracy or Majoritarian Pluralism.

Information

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Arrow, Kenneth J. 1963 [1951]. Social Choice and Individual Values. 2d ed. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Bachrach, Peter, and Baratz, Morton S.. 1962. “Two Faces of Power.” American Political Science Review 56(4): 947–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, Larry M. 2008. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age. New York: Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bauer, Raymond A., Pool, Ithiel de Sola, and Dexter, Lewis Anthony. 1967. American Business and Public Policy: The Politics of Foreign Trade. New York: Atherton.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., Berry, Jeffrey M., Hojnacki, Marie, Kimball, David C., and Leech, Beth L.. 2009. Lobbying and Policy Change: Who Wins, Who Loses, and Why. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beard, Charles A. 2012 [1913]. An Economic Interpretation of the Constitution of the United States. New York, Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Bentley, Arthur F. 1908. The Process of Government: A Study of Social Pressures. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Berry, Jeffrey M. 1999. The New Liberalism: The Rising Power of Citizen Groups. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1948. “On the Rationale of Group Decision-making.” Journal of Political Economy 56: 2334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Block, Fred. 1977. “The Ruling Class Does Not Rule: Notes on the Marxist Theory of the State.” Socialist Revolution 7(3): 628.Google Scholar
Block, Fred. 2007. “Understanding the Divergent Trajectories of the United States and Western Europe: A Neo-Polanyian Analysis.” Politics and Society (March): 131.Google Scholar
Burch, Philip H. 1980-81. Elites in American History. 3 vol. New York: Holmes & Meier.Google Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Herron, Michael C., and Shotts, Kenneth W.. 2001. “Leadership and Pandering: A Theory of Executive Policymaking.” American Journal of Political Science 45: 532–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1956. A Preface to Democratic Theory. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1961. Who Governs? New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1989. Democracy and its Critics. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, Otto A., Hinich, Melvin J., and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1970. “An Expository Development of a Mathematical Model of the Electoral Process.” American Political Science Review 64(2): 426–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domhoff, G. William. 2013. Who Rules America: The Triumph of the Corporate Rich. 7th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert S., MacKuen, Michael B., and Stimson, James A.. 2002. The Macro Polity. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert S., Wright, Gerald C., and McIver, John P.. 1993. Statehouse Democracy: Public Opinion and Policy in the American States. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ferguson, Thomas. 1995. Golden Rule: The Investment Theory of Party Competition and the Logic of Money-Driven Political Systems. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, Morris. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin. 2011. “Two-thirds Full? Citizen Competence and Democratic Governance.” In New Directions in Public Opinion, ed. Berinsky, Adam. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in America. New York: Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S., and Pierson, Paul. 2010. Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich Richer—and Turned its Back on the Middle Class. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Alexander, Madison, James, and Jay, John. 1961 [1787–88]. The Federalist Papers, ed. Rossiter, Clinton. New York: New American Library.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotelling, Harold. 1929. “Stability in Competition.” Economic Journal 39: 4157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, Jeffrey. 1987a. “Beyond the Three Faces of Power: A Realist Critique.” Polity 20(1): 431.Google Scholar
Isaac, Jeffrey. 1987b. Power and Marxist Theory. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Jacobs, Larry R., and Page, Benjamin I.. 2005. “Who Influences U.S. Foreign Policy?American Political Science Review 99(1): 107–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katznelson, Ira. 2013. Fear Itself: The New Deal and the Origins of Our Time. New York: Liveright.Google Scholar
Key, V.O. Jr. 1961. Public Opinion and American Democracy. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
Lindblom, Charles E. 1977. Politics and Markets. New York: Basic.Google Scholar
Lincoln, Abraham. 1989 [1863]. “Address at Gettysburg, Pennsylvania.” In Speeches and Writings 1859–1865. New York: Library of America.Google Scholar
Lukes, Steven. 1974. Power: A Radical View. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansbridge, Jane. 2003. “Rethinking Representation.” American Political Science Review 97(4): 515–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, Karl, and Engels, Friedrich. 1972 [18481888]. Manifesto of the Communist Party . In The Marx-Engels Reader, ed. Tucker, Robert C.. New York: W.W. Norton. See also http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch01.htm Google Scholar
May, Kenneth O. 1952. “A Set of Independent Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for Simple Majority Decisions.” Econometrica 20: 680–84.Google Scholar
McChesney, Fred S. 1997. Money for Nothing: Politicians, Rent Extraction, and Political Extortion. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
McConnell, Grant. 1966. Private Power and American Democracy. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard. 1976. “ Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control.” Journal of Economic Theory 12: 472–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michels, Robert. 2001 [1911]. Political Parties: A Sociological Study of the Oligarchical Tendencies of Modern Democracy. Kitchener, Ontario: Batoche Books.Google Scholar
Milbrath, Lester W. 1963. The Washington Lobbyists. Chicago, IL: Rand-McNally.Google Scholar
Miliband, Ralph. 1969. The State in Capitalist Society. New York: Basic.Google Scholar
Mills, C. Wright. 1959 [1956]. The Power Elite. Galaxy edition. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Monroe, Alan D. 1979. “Consistency between Public Preferences and National Policy Decisions.” American Politics Quarterly 7: 318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Monroe, Alan D. 1998. “Public Opinion and Public Policy 1980–1993.” Public Opinion Quarterly 68: 628.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Page, Benjamin I., Bartels, Larry M., and Seawright, Jason. 2013. “Democracy and the Policy Preferences of Wealthy Americans.” Perspectives on Politics 11(1): 5173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, Benjamin I., and Hennessy, Cari Lynn. 2008. “What Affluent Americans Want from Politics.” WP-11-08. Institute for Policy Research, Northwestern University.Google Scholar
Page, Benjamin I., and Jacobs, Lawrence R.. 2009. Class War? What Americans Really Think about Economic Inequality. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, Benjamin I., and Shapiro, Robert Y.. 1983. “Effects of Public Opinion on Policy.” American Political Science Review 77(1): 175–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, Benjamin I. 1992. The Rational Public: Fifty Years of Trends in Americans’ Policy Preferences. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith, and Rosenthal, Howard. 2007. Ideology and Congress. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Przeworksi, Adam, and Wallerstein, Michael. 1982. “The Structure of Class Conflict in Democratic Capitalist Societies.” American Political Science Review 76(2): 215–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schattschneider, E.E. 1935. Politics, Pressures and the Tariff. New York: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E.E. 1960. The Semi-Sovereign People: A Realist’s View of Democracy in America. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Schlozman, Kay Lehman, Verba, Sidney, and Brady, Henry E.. 2012. The Unheavenly Chorus: Unequal Political Voice and the Broken Promise of American Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya K. 1970. Collective Choice and Social Welfare. San Francisco, CA: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1992. Protecting Soldiers and Mothers: The Political Origins of Social Policy in the United States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skocpol, Theda, and Finegold, Kenneth. 1982. “State Capacity and Economic Intervention in the Early New Deal.” Political Science Quarterly 97: 255–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Mark A. 2000. American Business and Political Power: Public Opinion, Elections, and Democracy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1971. “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2(1): 321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stimson, James A., MacKuen, Michael B., and Erikson, Robert S.. 1995. “Dynamic Representation.” American Political Science Review 89(3): 543–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tocqueville, Alexis de. 2000 [1835–1840]. Democracy in America. Trans. and ed. Mansfield, Harvey C. and Winthrop, Delba. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Truman, David B. 1971 [1951]. The Governmental Process. 2d. ed. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
U.S. Census Bureau, 2013. “Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage: 2012” (September). Available at http://www.census.gov/newsroom/releases/pdf/20130917_ip_slides_with_plotpoints.pdf.Google Scholar
Winters, Jeffrey A. 2011. Oligarchy. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winters, Jeffrey A., and Page, Benjamin I.. 2009. “Oligarchy in the United States?Perspectives on Politics 7(4): 731–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfinger, Raymond E., and Rosenstone, Steven J.. 1980. Who Votes? New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Zaller, John. 2003. “Coming to Terms with V.O. Key’s Concept of Latent Opinion.” In Electoral Democracy, ed. MacKuen, Michael B. and Rabinowitz, George. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Gilens Supplementary Material

Gilens Supplementary Material 1

Download Gilens Supplementary Material(File)
File 78.2 KB
Supplementary material: File

Gilens Supplementary Material

Gilens Supplementary Material 2

Download Gilens Supplementary Material(File)
File 39.3 KB
Supplementary material: PDF

Gilens Supplementary Material

Gilens Supplementary Material 3

Download Gilens Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 38 KB
Supplementary material: PDF

Gilens Supplementary Material

Gilens Supplementary Material 4

Download Gilens Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 16.3 KB
Supplementary material: PDF

Gilens Supplementary Material

Gilens Supplementary Material 5

Download Gilens Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 35.6 KB
Supplementary material: File

Gilens Supplementary Material

Gilens Supplementary Material 6

Download Gilens Supplementary Material(File)
File 4.4 MB