Hostname: page-component-6bb9c88b65-6scc2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-07-23T14:02:40.549Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Impacts of a U.S.-led tariff war on international trade in wine, beer, and spirits

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 July 2025

Kym Anderson*
Affiliation:
Wine Economics Research Centre, School of Economics and Public Policy, University of Adelaide, Adelaide, SA, Australia Arndt-Corden Department of Economics, Australian National University, Canberra, ACT, Australia
Glyn Wittwer
Affiliation:
Centre of Policy Studies, Victoria University, Melbourne, VIC, Australia
*
Corresponding author: Kym Anderson; Email: kym.anderson@adelaide.edu.au

Abstract

The announcements by President Trump in April 2025, of unilateral hikes of 10–50 percentage points on U.S. import tariffs on all countries’ goods, are under threat of coming into force on July 9, 2025. This article estimates their likely effects on trade in alcoholic beverages, using a global model of national beverage markets. Various scenarios are compared. They suggest that if the tariff hike was restricted to just 20% on goods from the European Union, the value of global trade in each of the three beverages would shrink by one-tenth. But the U.S. tariff hikes are to apply to all countries’ goods, which are estimated to shrink global exports by 13% for wine, 22% for spirits and 33% for beer. In that broader scenario, most countries’ wine exports would shrink, but exports of beer and spirits would expand for some countries thanks to the trade divergence generated by the varying tariff hikes. If the increasing uncertainty associated with these developments led to a cumulated 2% drop in consumer spending, virtually all wine-exporting countries would sell less wine to both the U.S. and the rest of the world. That is, wine trade destruction would outweigh trade diversion.

Information

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of American Association of Wine Economists.

I. Introduction

A media report in March 2025 suggested that if the U.S. imposed a 25% tariff on its imports of products from not only Canada, China, and Mexico but also from the European Union (EU), it would wipe U.S.$1.1 billion off the value of Italian wine exports. This article began by seeking to check on that Italian claim, and at the same time explore the impacts on other countries’ exports and on U.S. imports of alcoholic beverages of such unilateral U.S. action – and of possible retaliation by its trading partners. The fact that the U.S. accounts for 16% of the volume of global consumption of wine (and 13% of beer and 8% of spirits), and around 20% by value, means this unilateral action by the U.S. will have nontrivial effects on global beverage markets, especially for wine.

The promised wide use of tariffs by U.S. President Trump started immediately in his second term, beginning with 25% tariffs on U.S. imports of steel and aluminum from its various trading partners. That triggered retaliation threats by some affected countries. One of the first notable examples, in March 2025, was the EU’s threat to impose 50% tariffs on its imports of U.S. whiskey from April. President Trump immediately counterthreatened to impose 200% tariffs on U.S. imports of all EU wines, beers, and spirits, causing the EU to reconsider its reaction and delay its planned date to implement retaliation.

Such tariff wars reduce global trade and overall economic welfare but very unevenly, with some groups winning at the expense of others. For example, if the U.S. raised taxes on EU beverage imports, wine exports from the southern hemisphere to the U.S. might expand. However, the increasing uncertainty associated with these developments and threats – which were even greater in April than in February 2025 as depicted in Figure 1—is reducing consumer and investor confidence. That in turn is dampening economic growth and the prices of U.S. stocks, and thus households’ willingness to spend in many countries including the U.S. This global disruption is thus very different from the COVID-19 pandemic: COVID caused a deep economic recession, but it was by far the shortest in the U.S. postwar period, and the recovery was remarkably rapid (Stock and Watson, Reference Stock and Watson2025).

Figure 1. Global trade policy uncertainty index, January 1960–February 2025.

It is unclear how President Trump’s dramatic escalation of U.S. tariff hikes on April 2, 2025 (temporarily lowered to 10% for 90 days from April 9, except for Chinese goods, which were escalated to 145%) and his associated economic coercion, and other countries’ responses including retaliations, will play out.

Nonetheless, there is value in considering alternative scenarios and estimating their likely trade impacts. One way to do that is to employ a global empirical trade model of national markets. Economy-wide models such as GTAP are already being used to do that (e.g., Giesecke and Waschik, Reference Giesecke and Waschik2025). However, the commodity aggregation necessary to make those models tractable does not provide the detail that some industries seek.

In this paper, we draw on a global model by Wittwer and Anderson (Reference Anderson2020) that was developed specifically to explore international trade in wine, beer, and spirits. We use it here to estimate the trade consequences of a range of scenarios, based on the U.S. tariff announcements of April 2 and some retaliation announcements by policymakers in partner countries.

While one might expect a tariff war in the northern hemisphere to benefit less-affected southern hemisphere wine exporters, the latter gains would be smaller and possibly more than offset if overall growth in global demand for beverages were to slow down because of the uncertainty-induced drop in consumer and investor confidence and thus in projected rates of economic growth. In March 2025, the OECD projected U.S. GDP growth to be 0.6 percentage points lower in 2025 than in 2024, and a further 0.6 points lower in 2026 (OECD, 2025). Following the April 2 tariff shocks from Washington, larger-sized adjustments have been made to output growth projections for many countries, including China, and to their impact on trade growth projections (see, e.g., IMF, 2025; WTO, 2025). Those U.S. tariffs may be lowered by the time they are scheduled to be implemented from July 9 as the Trump administration seeks to do “deals” with the EU and individual countries one at a time. However, the U.S. is also seeking to persuade its trading partners to isolate China economically.

In the next section of this article, the basic theory of tariffs and pertinent trade policy experience is briefly summarized. Section III then describes the key features of the model of global beverage markets to be used in this analysis. Various scenarios to be modeled are listed in Section IV, before the results in terms of bilateral and total trade flows are summarized sequentially in Section V. Some caveats are raised in the discussion of Section VI. The final section draws conclusions from the analysis.

II. Basic theory and past experience

It has been well understood for millennia, at least since Plato’s Republic (375 BC), that trade between two entities can be beneficial to both. The reason why that applies to countries was made very clear more than two centuries ago by Ricardo (Reference Ricardo1817) with his theory of comparative advantage. Ricardo showed that even the most technologically advanced nation with the lowest production costs in the world could benefit by specializing in exporting just a subset of products—those it is best at producing—and importing all other products.

Yet most countries still have tariffs on some imports, even though they reduce trade, global welfare, and the economic welfare of each distorting nation that is not large enough to be able to influence its international terms of trade (the price of their exports relative to the price of their imports).

True, a few economies may be large enough to improve their terms of trade by imposing trade taxes. However, the nationally optimal rate of that tax on trade, even for the world’s largest economy (the U.S.), would be small (Itskhoki and Mukhin, Reference Itskhoki and Mukhin2025). In any case, any potential benefit is easily and quickly diminished the more the tariff-imposing country’s trading partners retaliate in kind (Johnson, Reference Johnson1953). Thus, even the largest economies have seen value in international cooperation to desist from exploiting that power via trade taxes when retaliation is likely.

Britain was the first to test Ricardo’s theory in the industrial era, by repealing its Corn Laws in 1846. That allowed it to specialize more in manufacturing and depend more on imports of lower-priced foods and fibers and thereby become the wealthiest country in the world (even though, as shown by Irwin and Chepeliev (Reference Irwin and Chepeliev2021), the reform benefitted the rest of the world as well as Britain due to its influence on the international terms of trade). Britain’s GDP was matched by the U.S. only around 1860, as the U.S. population grew rapidly through immigration, and Britain’s GDP per capita continued to exceed that of the U.S. until 1900 (Maddison, Reference Maddison2007).

In 1860, the signing of the Cobden–Chevalier Treaty liberalized trade between Britain and France. That bilateral treaty included a most-favored-nation (MFN) clause, which required any agreed tariff cut offered to another country would also be applied to imports of that good from this newly signed partner (Viner, Reference Viner1924). It was in their interest to so agree also because that ensured smaller European countries that subsequently signed a bilateral trade treaty with either Britain or France (and most had done so by 1867) also signed onto MFN. The systemic effect of the 1860 Anglo-French accord was thus of much greater significance than its importance to either country alone or even the two together, as it led to a network of treaties that lowered hugely the average level of import tariff protection during 1860–1913, and meant the world enjoyed relative serenity in terms of international trade and monetary relations (Kindleberger, Reference Kindleberger1975). Even though economic growth then was proceeding at less than half the post-World War II pace, it was very rapid by previous standards, as was international trade growth.

However, just when many of the European trade treaties were reaching their expiry date (nearly 50 of them were to expire in the first half of the 1890s), economic difficulties were making their renegotiation contentious and leading to trade tensions. Tariff wars ensued, so that the threat of retaliation, which had served as a deterrent to raising tariffs, was no longer sufficient as a constraint on trade liberalization reversal. Even though MFN was retained, relations were strained by the absence of bindings on tariffs (to prevent backsliding), of constraints on nontariff trade-distorting measures, and of legal means to resolve disputes. Furthermore, the unwillingness of the U.S. or others to adopt the unconditional MFN principle meant the sustainability of the European commercial policy achievements of that period was far from certain. Indeed, the treaty regime ended abruptly with the outbreak of World War I in 1914.

Postwar efforts to restore liberal trade centered on international conferences. However, despite the rhetoric in support of open markets, those meetings did not lead to renewed trade treaties with binding commitments to openness based on MFN. With no country willing or able to replace Britain as the hegemon, there was trade policy anarchy (Kindleberger, Reference Kindleberger, Mathias and Pollard1989). When economic recession hit in the late 1920s, and the U.S. introduced the Smoot–Hawley tariff hikes of June 1930, governments elsewhere responded with beggar-thy-neighbor protectionist trade policies including imperial trading agreements that together helped drive the world economy into depression. Among those “agreements,” Hitler coerced Germany’s smaller neighbors into signing bilateral trade treaties that were highly skewed in Germany’s favor (Hirschman, Reference Hirschman1945, Reference Hirschman1977). The volume of world trade shrunk by one-quarter between 1929 and 1932, and its value fell by two-fifths. Over the entire two-decade interwar period, merchandise trade grew hardly at all (Kindleberger, Reference Kindleberger1973).

The first attempts to reverse the growth in protection were discriminatory, benefitting Europe’s colonies at the expense of other trading partners. While some of those imperial trade agreements were trade creating, others diverted trade from lowest-cost suppliers and so were far from optimal from a global perspective (Viner, Reference Viner1950). By the end of the 1930s, protectionism was far more entrenched than in the late 19th century when only nondiscriminatory tariffs had to be grappled with. Indeed nontariff trade barriers were so rife as to make tariffs redundant and hence a return to MFN irrelevant unless and until “tariffication” of those barriers occurred.

Out of the interwar trade policy experience, many in Britain and the U.S. were convinced that liberal world trade required a set of multilaterally agreed rules and binding commitments based on nondiscriminatory principles. After much negotiation, that led to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). It was signed in 1947 by 23 trading countries who at the time accounted for nearly two-thirds of the world’s international trade. The GATT provided a forum to negotiate subsequent tariff reductions and changes in rules, plus a mechanism to help settle trade disputes. Eight so-called rounds of negotiations were completed in the subsequent 46 years, as a result of which many import tariffs on at least manufactured goods were progressively lowered in most high-income countries. Global merchandise trade grew faster in the half century following the coming into force of the GATT than in any other half century in history.

The last of those GATT negotiations, the Uruguay Round (1986–1994), culminated in numerous agreements to further reduce trade barriers over the subsequent decade. Another agreement involved the GATT’s Secretariat in Geneva being replaced by a new World Trade Organization (WTO) in January 1995. As shown by Saggi (Reference Saggi2009), openness is easier to sustain under MFN rules than under discriminatory preferential ones, which helps explain why 166 nations, representing 98% of world trade, have chosen to become members of the WTO and another 20 are negotiating to join.

Despite the strong theoretical case and ample empirical evidence in favor of trade openness (Irwin, Reference Irwin1996, Reference Irwin2020) and of an MFN rules-based WTO (Anderson, Reference Anderson2016), most countries continue to impose at least some trade-restrictive policies. Those hardest-to-reform policies persist because of strong domestic political economy forces at work that favor some protectionism. Meanwhile, past policy reforms plus technological advances have fragmented production along value chains, which has greatly increased incentives for countries to reduce their trade restrictions (Baldwin, Reference Baldwin2016). They have also been contributing to the eventual structural transformation of growing economies away from producing primary products and basic manufactures and toward services.

Yet Donald Trump seems unconvinced. He apparently believes import protectionism can boost U.S. manufacturing and income growth, reduce bilateral trade deficits, provide enough extra customs revenue to allow income tax cuts,Footnote 1 and strengthen U.S. negotiating power to coerce other countries to open up their markets to U.S. producers and to restrict their trade with China. He has therefore been determined to raise U.S. tariffs even further during his second term than in his first. And in doing so in announcing on April 2, 2025 so-called “reciprocal” tariffs ranging from a minimum of 10% across all goods for all countries but ranging up to 50% (see Appendix Table 1), and in inviting one-on-one negotiations to lower each country’s “reciprocal” tariff, he has chosen to willfully violate the core principle of nondiscrimination as enshrined in Article I (General Most-Favoured-Nation Treatment) of the founding treaty of the GATT (and now also WTO).

The rest of the world has been forced to share in the cost of this unilateral U.S. action, which will be higher the greater and more prolonged is the continuing uncertainty associated with U.S. actions and others’ reactions and their adverse impacts on consumer and investor confidence and growth of capital (Baqaee and Malberg, Reference Baqaee and Malberg2025; Carballo et al., Reference Carballo, Handley and Limão2022). The trade consequences for each U.S. trading partner will depend on, among other things, the height of the U.S. tariff hike on goods imported from that country and from other supplying countries, the share of that country’s exports that flow to the U.S., the types of initial policy responses by its government and other countries’ governments (including any U.S.-coerced raising of their barriers to Chinese goods and FDI), and any antidumping actions triggered by affected countries lowering their export prices in their search for non-U.S. markets. Also important—but not modeled here—will be the trade-diverting effects of any subsequent bilateral deals struck with the U.S. that open up those partners’ trade to only U.S. exporters, and any follow-on counterretaliation by the U.S. against those partners that retaliate in kind rather than be coerced into a bilateral “deal” with the U.S. While it is still possible that the U.S. might be able to prize open some countries’ markets, history suggests this discriminatory approach to liberalization is very unlikely to boost global economic welfare even if the U.S. and/or some of its trading partners benefit.

III. Model

To analyze empirically the trade consequences of tariff hikes on wine and other alcoholic beverages requires a global model of national beverage markets connected through bilateral international trade flows, in which the interactions between each nation’s producers and consumers of those beverages are recognized. Wittwer and Anderson (Reference Anderson2020) provide such a model, the GLOBAL-BEV model. It identifies three red still wine qualities, three white still wine qualities, and sparkling wine, in addition to having a beer sector and a spirits sector in each country. It also distinguishes on-premise from off-premise sales of each type of beverage, the former (pubs, restaurants, etc.) having much bigger retail mark-ups on the tariff- and tax-inclusive wholesale prices of alcoholic beverages than sales for off-premise consumption.

In the GLOBAL-BEV model, the world is divided into 44 individual beverage-trading nations, with all other countries being captured in seven composite residual regions (listed in Appendix Table 1). The primary sources of data for constructing the model’s baseline database are Anderson and Pinilla (Reference Anderson and Pinilla2024) plus Anderson (Reference Anderson2020) for taxes on beverage consumption and imports, Holmes and Anderson (Reference Holmes and Anderson2017) for wine, beer, and spirits average consumer expenditure data, and the United Nations (2024) for volume and value of international trade in beverages.

The GLOBAL-BEV model has income- and price-responsive demand equations, price-responsive supply equations, and hence quantities and prices for each of the grape and wine products and for beer and spirits, plus for a single composite of all other products in each country, such that it has elements of an economy-wide model. Grapes are assumed to not be traded internationally, but other products are both exported and imported by each country from potentially every other country.

We shock the baseline of this model by raising tariffs on U.S. imports from the various countries and then also by those of its targeted trading partners who are assumed to retaliate. The tariff rate hikes announced by President Trump on April 2, 2025 and are scheduled to come into effect a week later, are listed in Appendix Table 1.

To illustrate, if the U.S. had a 7% MFN tariff on a product, then imports of that product would now be subject to a tariff of (7 + 10 = ) 17% if it came from the UK and (7 + 20 = ) 27% if it came from the EU. In the case of China, the 20% tariff hike on its goods, announced by the U.S. in March, is added to the additional 34% hike announced on April 2, so its new tariff would be (7 + 20 + 34 = ) 61% on that product. Then on April 10 the U.S. raised its tariff hike to 145% on goods from China and Hong Kong (a change that came too late for including in this analysis, but it is not important for this study since their beverage exports to the U.S. are negligible).

IV. Simulation scenarios

The baseline of the global beverage markets model is shocked to simulate the following scenarios, each building on the preceding one:

  1. 1. The U.S. imposes a 20% tariff on imports of all wine, beer and spirits from the EU;

  2. 2. Simulation 1 plus the U.S. imposes tariff hikes on all wine, beer and spirits imports from all other countries at the rates listed in Appendix Table 1;

  3. 3. Simulation 2 plus, in retaliation, Canada, China, and all other Asian countries impose a tariff hike on all their wine, beer, and spirits imports from the U.S. at the same rate as the U.S. has imposed tariff hikes on each item from them; and

  4. 4. Simulation 3 plus a slowdown in global economic growth as a result of these and other trade wars triggered by the Trump Administration’s trade policy upheaval (simulated as a medium-term cumulative reduction in all consumer expenditure of 2% in all countries relative to the benchmark).

The EU, UK, Australia, and other countries have indicated they would not be immediately retaliating by imposing tariffs on U.S. goods. China has raised its tariff hike on U.S. goods to 125% and thereafter will use other means such as nontariff import barriers and restrictions on its exports to the U.S. of critical minerals. The EU plans to negotiate but may also retaliate by July 8, possibly by restricting imports of U.S. services rather than goods. The extent and timing of other responses and any U.S. counter-retaliation or new bilateral deals (that may include value-chain-disrupting rules of origin aimed at disrupting China’s attempts to circumvent U.S. restrictions) are unknown at this stage. But the uncertainty associated with them will itself slow global economic growth and is the reason for including Simulation 4 in the above list.

V. Model results

The results suggest Italy’s wine exports would be reduced by only a fraction of the U.S.$1.1 billion/year predicted by the news clipping reported in the opening of this article. The global model’s first three simulation results suggest Italy’s loss in wine exports to the U.S. would be less than one-third of that amount. They also suggest that Italy would export more wine to the rest of the world, such that its net loss would be less than one-fifth of the value predicted in that news item, other things equal. Those simulations assume, though, that consumer expenditure is not dampened by the tariff war. Should there be a global slowdown in expenditure as a result of the tariff war as modelled in Simulation 4, however, that global loss in Italy’s wine exports may be close to U.S.$500 million per year, because the quantity of wine demanded in not only the U.S. but also the rest of the world would shrink (Table 1). That is a nontrivial sum, even if it is still less than half what that news clipping suggested.

Table 1. Impacts on annual value of Italy’s wine exports of a U.S.-triggered tariff war (2025 U.S.$ million)

Source: Authors’ model results.

This is but a small sample of the many trade results generated from the global beverage markets model. The rest of this section summarizes other key results generated from the above-listed simulations.

a. Simulation 1: A 20% hike in tariffs on U.S. imports of alcoholic beverage from the EU

The unilateral imposition of the 20% hike in tariffs on U.S. imports of beverages from the EU would wipe 18% off the annual value of EU wine exports to the U.S. and $564 million off the value of the EU’s total wine exports (Table 2). As well, the value of U.S. imports from the EU of beer would shrink by 49%, and that of spirits by 42%. In dollar terms, the total net loss in annual wine export sales would be $196 million for France, $268 million for Italy and $44 million for Spain. Italy’s loss includes its Prosecco trade, as the average price of sparkling wine in the U.S. would rise by 7% and the volume consumed there would drop by 4% in this scenario—about twice as much as for still wines (Table 3).

Table 2. Impacts on annual value of U.S. beverage imports from selected economies of a U.S.-triggered tariff war (%)

Source: Authors’ model results.

Table 3. Impacts on U.S. consumer prices and the volume of sales of beverages in the U.S. of a U.S.-triggered tariff war (%)

Source: Authors’ model results.

As always from such discriminatory trade practices, other exporters could gain via trade diversion even though the value of all beverage exports to the U.S. shrink by about 10%. For example, if only the EU was targeted, the value of U.S. imports from the UK of beer would rise by 15% and that of spirits (and wine) by 19%. Meanwhile, annual U.S. wine imports from the southern hemisphere’s wine-exporting countries would rise by between 10% and 18% (Table 2). But those countries’ wine exports to the rest of the world would shrink by $96 million, such that their net gain would be only $78 million (last row for Simulation 1 in Table 4).

Table 4. Impacts of the U.S.-triggered tariff war on annual value of wine exports to the U.S. and rest of world from selected economies (2025 U.S.$ million)

Source: Authors’ model results.

b. Simulation 2: A hike in tariffs on U.S. imports of alcoholic beverages from all countries

If U.S. beverage imports from not just the EU but all countries were subjected to the tariff hikes as listed in Appendix Table 1, the value of EU beverage exports to the U.S. would decline by only a little less than in the first simulation. For U.S. imports from the world as a whole, the hit would be −13% for wine, −33% for beer, and −22% for spirits. That is a major reversal of involvement by the U.S. in beverage market globalization. But some exporting countries would gain while others lose in their sales to this market (Table 2). The impact on beverage volumes consumed in the U.S. would be only slightly greater in this scenario compared with the first (Table 3).

The EU’s exports to the U.S. fall by less in this scenario because the southern hemisphere exporters lose instead of, as in Sim 1, gaining sales in the U.S.—and conversely for sales to the rest of the world. The global shrinkage is more than one-third larger than in Sim 1 though. Changes in wine exports to the rest of the world mostly have the opposite sign for each country to the changes in their exports to the U.S. (Table 4).

c. Simulation 3: Simulation 2 plus matching retaliatory tariff hikes on alcoholic beverage imports from the U.S. by Canada, China, and other Asian countries

If Canada and Asia were to retaliate by imposing matching tariff hikes on their imports of U.S. beverages, it would add only slightly to the fall in the imports of wine by the U.S., to 16%. That would be shared fairly equally in terms of a greater reduction in wine exports to the U.S. than in Sim 1 from the countries listed in Table 2. This greater reduction in wine exported to the U.S. in this scenario than in the previous one is because of the loss of U.S. export sales from such retaliation, which ensures there are more of its own wines available locally. The fall in global exports is one-sixth more than in Sim 2 (Table 4).

Exports of U.S. wine to Canada would fall in this scenario by $270 million if (as we assume) preferences remain unchanged there. That would allow an extra $156 million worth of wine to Canada from the EU, along with an extra $13 million from Australia and $9 million from New Zealand. These are underestimates though, because there has been a strong preference swing in Canada against buying beverages and other goods from the U.S.

d. Simulation 4: Simulation 3 plus a 2% reduction in all consumer expenditure in all countries

These beverage tariff impositions are part of a more-comprehensive tariff war that is raising uncertainty and thus lowering consumer and investor confidence. If aggregate consumer expenditure were to be 2% lower everywhere than it otherwise would have been, the value of U.S. imports from the world would shrink by one-fifth for wine, by one-third for beer and by one-quarter for spirits (last row of Table 2). Consumer prices in the U.S. would rise least in this scenario because quantities demanded fall, as reflected in the larger drop in U.S. sales volume reported in Table 3.

The loss in value of EU wine exports to the world would be three times larger in this Sim than in Sims 1 and 2 and five times larger than in Sim 3. And in this fourth scenario, virtually all wine-exporting countries would sell less wine to both the U.S. and the rest of the world. For example, annual wine exports from the EU would be lower by $1.5 billion, that from the southern hemisphere by $0.4 billion, and that from all countries by $2.6 billion (Table 4). The differences in these impacts on wine exports across the four simulations are illustrated in Figure 2.

Source: Authors’ model results.

Figure 2. Impact of tariff hikes on the value of wine exports from the EU and all other wine exporters to the U.S. and to rest of world (2025 U.S.$ million).

The story for beer and spirits is more mixed even in this demand-shrinking scenario, with exports from the EU, Canada, Mexico, and China declining but exports from numerous smaller countries rising thanks to the trade-diverting effect of these unequal tariffs (Table 2). But the latter increases are partly because beer and spirits (and wine) consumption fall in every country in this fourth scenario, making more available for export.

China retaliated the next day to the U.S. tariff hike of 34% on its goods (which was added to the 20% hike the U.S. imposed on Chinese goods a month earlier). Table 5 summarizes the results on China’s wine imports for Sim 4 which includes that retaliation by China. It shows those imports decreasing from all countries, but the decreases are uneven across countries: unsurprisingly they fall most from the U.S., but the harm to Australia’s wine sales is not much less (columns 1 and 2 of Table 5). The shares in China’s wine imports fall three percentage points for both the U.S. and Italy, while those of Australia and France each rise by about half those amounts (column 3 of Table 5). But China’s share in the exports of all countries fall, and global wine exports to China are estimated to be lowered by 0.4% thanks to this latest tariff war (column 4 of Table 5). That would add to the decline in China’s role in global wine markets that has been going on since the mid-2010s (Anderson, Reference Anderson2025).

Table 5. Estimated effects of the U.S.-led tariff war on the value of China’s imports of wine, by source country (2025 U.S.$ million and percentage points)

a Sim 4 assumes China’s retaliatory tariff hike on U.S. beverages is just 34%. Non-U.S. exporters would be estimated to replace more U.S. wines in China’s market if we had updated that tariff hike to 125%, as announced by China on April 10 following the announcement on April 9 that the U.S. “reciprocal” tariff hike on Chinese goods had been raised to 145%.

Source: Authors’ model results.

VI. Discussion

The above results make clear that the adverse trade effects of an imposition of tariffs by the U.S. are more costly, the more countries are targeted and the more those targeted countries retaliate with their own tariffs against U.S. products. They also show that the impact can be very uneven across countries with few gaining directly but all losing if there is a sufficiently large loss of consumer confidence and thus expenditure because of the tariff war.

Of course the costs also would be larger, the higher are those tariff hikes. In March 2025, the EU initially threatened to impose 50% tariffs against its imports of U.S. whiskey from April, for example (in retaliation for the 25% tariffs the U.S. imposed in March on imports of steel and aluminum)—to which President Trump immediately responded by claiming he would counterretaliate with 200% tariffs on U.S. imports of EU beverages. While the latter did not happen because the EU chose to withdraw their threat later that month, it illustrates the potential snowballing costliness of tariff wars when governments are willing to contemplate retaliation and counterretaliation.

The above results refer only to the damage to beverage trade, and have not taken into account the potential impacts on the cost of imported inputs into the domestic beverage industries (bottles, barrels, cans, corks, machinery), nor on foreign investment flows and each country’s real exchange rates (bearing in mind that the tariff war is affecting all goods and all countries).Footnote 2 Australia’s dollar, for example, was devalued immediately following the announced U.S. tariff hike on goods from China and other Asian countries because of Australia’s close links with and comprehensive exports of raw materials to East Asia. While that AUD devaluation thereby eases somewhat the direct tariff pain on Australia’s wine and other export industries, there could well be further consequences such as from antidumping duties imposed by countries seeking to protect their import-competing industries from lowered international prices.

VII. Conclusions

A clear lesson from the above results is that while some countries could gain from a U.S.-led tariff assault if one considers only the trade-diverting effects of the initial tariffs, most will lose if it leads to an escalating tariff war that reduces growth in overall consumer expenditure even only slightly (as captured in Simulation 4 above). The longer the trade policy uncertainty prevails, the more costly will the war become not only to trading partners but also—and especially—to the U.S. economy. Even if the U.S. succeeds through its coercion in lowering some partner countries’ barriers to U.S. exports, that is unlikely to be enough to offset the damage done by adding to discrimination in the global trading system, particularly as and when China and others retaliate in kind.

More specifically, since the U.S. tariff shock has upset the delicate agreed balances that had emerged during eight decades of multilateral, regional, bilateral and other preferential trade negotiations, it will generate many more adjustments and subsequent trade negotiations not only with the U.S. but also among numerous groupings of non-U.S. countries scrambling to reduce the losses generated by this trade war.

Taking the U.S. to the WTO’s dispute settlement body is an option, but of no interest to member countries for three reasons: a case would take years to reach a conclusion; it would then be appealed by the U.S. but the WTO’s Appellate Body is unable to operate because the U.S. is unwilling to agree to the appointment of new members; and, even if it were able to present findings, they would be ignored by the current U.S. administration.

To end on a positive note, this war is generating renewed interest in Asian and other preferential trading arrangements that could be extended beyond their current reach to salvage the value chains that Trump’s tariffs have disrupted.

One is the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership Agreement (RCEP), a free trade agreement (FTA) involving, as of June 2023, 13 East Asian countries plus Australia and New Zealand that together account for about 30% of the world’s population and global GDP. It has an open invitation for India to join.

Another is the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP), which is a more-ambitious FTA signed in March 2018. It involves Canada and several Latin American and Western Pacific countries but neither the U.S. nor China. The UK joined CPTPP in December 2024, the first non-Asia Pacific country to do so; and China, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Taiwan, and Uruguay have formally applied to join.

Time will tell as to whether the U.S. chooses to remain outside these groups after the Trump presidency. If so, and if the U.S. continues to ignore the WTO, the rest of the world will nonetheless have opportunities to increase openness in various other ways and grow despite the U.S. being less engaged with it. Meanwhile, one can hope that, just as China learnt in less than half a decade that its clumsy wolf-warrior diplomacy and economic coercion of the early 2020s is counterproductive, so too will the U.S.

Appendix

Table A1. Tariff rate hikes (additional to existing tariffs) imposed on U.S. imports of all goods including wine, beer, and spirits from the GLOBAL-BEV model’s countries listed below, effective from April 9, 2025a (percentage points)

a On April 9, these tariff hikes were temporarily lowered to 10% for the next 90 days; and on April 10, the U.S. raised its tariff hike to 145% on goods from China and Hong Kong (too late for including in this analysis, but not important for this study since their beverage exports to the U.S. are negligible).

Source: White House announcement of April 2, 2025.

Footnotes

This paper was presented at the opening plenary session of the 4th Annual Conference of the European Association of Wine Economists, Zaragoza, Spain, May 14–17, 2025. Thanks to conference participants, referees and the Managing Editor Karl Storchmann for helpful comments, and to Wine Australia, the University of Adelaide, and Victoria University in Melbourne for co-funding the development of the global model of national beverage markets.

1 A product’s tariff rate that maximizes national government revenue (tm) is higher than the optimal tariff rate from a large economy’s national economic welfare viewpoint. However, as rates are raised beyond tm, that tax revenue declines until it disappears at rates that drive the nation’s imports of that product to zero—as virtually happened when China imposed tariffs up to 218% on its imports of Australian wine during 2020–24 (Anderson, Reference Anderson2025).

2 Nor have they taken into account the U.S. duty drawback loophole that refunds duties such as tariffs paid on imported wine if a producer also exports wine of a similar value (Gabrielyan and Sumner, Reference Gabrielyan and Sumner2016; Spencer, Reference Spencer2024; Sumner et al., Reference Sumner, Lapsley and Rosen-Molina2012).

a On April 9, these tariff hikes were temporarily lowered to 10% for the next 90 days; and on April 10, the U.S. raised its tariff hike to 145% on goods from China and Hong Kong (too late for including in this analysis, but not important for this study since their beverage exports to the U.S. are negligible).

Source: White House announcement of April 2, 2025.

References

Anderson, K. (2016). Contributions of the GATT/WTO to global economic welfare: Empirical evidence. Journal of Economic Surveys, 30(1), 5692. doi:10.1111/joes.12087Google Scholar
Anderson, K. (2020). Consumer taxes on alcohol: An international comparison over time. Journal of Wine Economics, 15(1), 4270. doi:10.1017/jwe.2020.2Google Scholar
Anderson, K. (2025). China’s wine market: Recent shocks, long-term prospects. Journal of Wine Economics, 20, 2025. forthcomingGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K., and Pinilla, V. (2024). Annual Database of Global Wine Markets, 1835 to 2023. Wine Economics Research Centre, University of Adelaide. www.adelaide.edu.au/wine-econ/databases (accessed March 1, 2025).Google Scholar
Baldwin, R. (2016). The Great Convergence: Information Technology and the New Globalization. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Baqaee, D., and Malberg, H. (2025). Long-Run Effects of Trade Wars. NBER Working Paper No. 33702, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Carballo, J., Handley, K., and Limão, N.(2022).Economic and policy uncertainty: aggregate export dynamics and the value of agreements. Journal of International Economics, 139, Article 103661. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2022.103661Google Scholar
Gabrielyan, G. T., and Sumner, D. A. (2016). Wine Trade and the Economics of Import Duty and Excise Tax Drawbacks. American Association of Wine Economists 10th Annual Conference, Bordeaux, June 22.Google Scholar
Giesecke, J., and Waschik, R. (2025). Economic Analysis of U.S. Tariffs Introduced Over March-April 2025. CoPS Working Paper No. G-353, Victoria University.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. (1945). National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. (1977). The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before Its Triumph. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Holmes, A. J., and Anderson, K. (2017). Annual Database of National Beverage Consumption Volumes and Expenditures, 1950 to 2015, Wine Economics Research Centre, University of Adelaide. www.adelaide.edu.au/wine-econ/databases/alcohol-consumptionGoogle Scholar
IMF. (2025). World Economic Outlook. International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Irwin, D. (1996). Against the Tide: An Intellectual History of Free Trade Princeton Uinversity Press.Google Scholar
Irwin, D. (2020). Free Trade under Fire (5th edition). Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Irwin, D. A., and Chepeliev, M. G. (2021). The economic consequences of Sir Robert Peel: A quantitative assessment of the repeal of the corn laws. The Economic Journal, 131(640), 33223337. doi:10.1093/ej/ueab029Google Scholar
Itskhoki, O., and Mukhin, D. (2025). The optimal macro tariff. NBER Working Paper 33839, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Johnson, H. G. (1953). Optimal tariffs and retaliation. Review of Economic Studies, 1, 142153. doi:10.2307/2296006Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. (1973). The World in Depression, 1929-1939. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. (1975). The rise of free trade in Western Europe, 1820–1875. The Journal of Economic History, 35(1), 2055. doi:10.1017/S0022050700094298Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. (1989). Commercial policy between the wars In Mathias, P., and Pollard, S. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe Chapter II Vol. VIII, 161196. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (2007). Contours of the World Economy, 1-2030 AD: Essays in Macroeconomic History. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
OECD. (2025). OECD Economic Outlook, Interim Report March 2025: Steering through Uncertainty. doi:10.1787/89af4857-enGoogle Scholar
Ricardo, D. (1817). The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Cambridge University Press, reprinted 1981.Google Scholar
Saggi, K. (2009). The MFN clause, welfare, and multilateral cooperation between countries of unequal size. Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 132143. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2008.01.006Google Scholar
Spencer, S. (2024). Wine Duty Drawback – Another Dirty Secret! Lodi Winegrape Commission. https://lodigrowers.com/wine-duty-drawback-another-dirty-secret/Google Scholar
Stock, J. H., and Watson, M. W. (2025). Recovering from COVID. NBER Working Paper 33857.Google Scholar
Sumner, D. A., Lapsley, J. T., and Rosen-Molina, J. T. (2012). Economics of wine import duty and excise tax drawbacks. In: ARE Update (14. Vol. 15). University of California Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics. https://giannini.ucop.edu/filer/file/1453327761/16882/Google Scholar
United Nations (2024). COMTRADE Database. https://comtrade.un.org/db (accessed March 1, 2025).Google Scholar
Viner, J. (1924). The most-favored-nation clause in American commercial treaties. Journal of Political Economy, 32(1), 101129. doi:10.1086/253580Google Scholar
Viner, J. (1950). The Customs Union Issue. Carnegie Endowment for World Peace.Google Scholar
Wittwer, G., and Anderson, K. (2020). A model of global beverage markets. Journal of Wine Economics, 15(3), 330354. doi:10.1017/jwe.2020.17Google Scholar
WTO. (2025). Global Trade Outlook and Statistics. World Trade Organization.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Global trade policy uncertainty index, January 1960–February 2025.

Figure 1

Table 1. Impacts on annual value of Italy’s wine exports of a U.S.-triggered tariff war (2025 U.S.$ million)

Figure 2

Table 2. Impacts on annual value of U.S. beverage imports from selected economies of a U.S.-triggered tariff war (%)

Figure 3

Table 3. Impacts on U.S. consumer prices and the volume of sales of beverages in the U.S. of a U.S.-triggered tariff war (%)

Figure 4

Table 4. Impacts of the U.S.-triggered tariff war on annual value of wine exports to the U.S. and rest of world from selected economies (2025 U.S.$ million)

Figure 5

Figure 2. Impact of tariff hikes on the value of wine exports from the EU and all other wine exporters to the U.S. and to rest of world (2025 U.S.$ million).

Source: Authors’ model results.
Figure 6

Table 5. Estimated effects of the U.S.-led tariff war on the value of China’s imports of wine, by source country (2025 U.S.$ million and percentage points)

Figure 7

Table A1. Tariff rate hikes (additional to existing tariffs) imposed on U.S. imports of all goods including wine, beer, and spirits from the GLOBAL-BEV model’s countries listed below, effective from April 9, 2025a (percentage points)