Hostname: page-component-6bb9c88b65-fsdjw Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-07-24T10:18:39.802Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Migration, child education, human capital accumulation, and a brain dilution tax

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 May 2025

Leonid V. Azarnert*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, HSE University, 3A Kantemirovskaya St., St Petersburg, Russia
Get access

Abstract

I study the effect of educational policy in the host economy on human capital accumulation and growth. The analysis is performed in a two-country growth model with endogenous fertility. I show that providing additional free educational services for immigrant children can increase the attractiveness of migration for less skilled individuals, which can outweigh the positive effect of this policy on the acquisition of human capital. In contrast, imposing taxes on immigrants in the host country reduces low-skilled immigration flows and has the potential to promote human capital accumulation if the resulting revenues are channeled into educational subsidies.

Information

Type
Research Paper
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press in association with Université catholique de Louvain

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Aksan, A.-M., & Chakraborty, S. (2014). Mortality versus morbidity in the demographic transition. European Economic Review, 70, 470492.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2014.06.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Algan, Y., Dustmann, C., Glitz, A., & Manning, A. (2010). The economic situation of first and second-generation immigrants in France, Germany and United Kingdom. Economic Journal, 120, 430.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02338.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2008). Foreign aid, fertility and human capital accumulation. Economica, 75, 776781.10.1111/j.1468-0335.2007.00661.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2009). Abortion and human capital accumulation: A contribution to the understanding of the gender gap in education. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 56, 559579.10.1111/j.1467-9485.2009.00498.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2010a). Free education, fertility and human capital accumulation. Journal of Population Economics, 23, 449468.10.1007/s00148-008-0205-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2010b). Is skilled immigration always good for growth in the receiving economy? Economics Letters, 108, 116118.10.1016/j.econlet.2010.04.032CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2010c). Après nous le déluge: Fertility and the intensity of struggle against immigration. Journal of Population Economics, 23, 13391349.10.1007/s00148-009-0263-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2014). Integrated public education, fertility and human capital. Education Economics, 22, 166180.10.1080/09645292.2011.601931CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2018). Refugee resettlement, redistribution and growth. European Journal of Political Economy, 54, 8998.10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.03.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2019). Migration, congestion and growth. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 23, 30353064.10.1017/S1365100517001043CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2020). Health capital provision and human capital accumulation. Oxford Economic Papers, 72, 633665.10.1093/oep/gpaa004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azarnert, L.V. (2023). Population sorting and human capital accumulation. Oxford Economic Papers, 75, 780801.10.1093/oep/gpac035CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bahar, D., Hauptmann, A., Ozguzel, C., & Rapoport, H. (2024). Migration and knowledge diffusion: The effect of returning refugees on export performance in the former Yugoslavia. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 106, 287304.10.1162/rest_a_01165CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayer, C., & Juessen, F. (2012). On the dynamics of interstate migration: Migration costs and self-selection. Review of Economic Dynamics, 15, 377401.10.1016/j.red.2012.02.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beine, M., Docquier, F., & Rapoport, H. (2008). Brain drain and human capital formation in developing countries: Winners and losers. Economic Journal, 118, 631652.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2008.02135.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canaday, N., & Tamura, R. (2009). White discrimination in provision of black education: Plantations and towns. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 33, 14901530.10.1016/j.jedc.2009.02.012CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D., & Doepke, M. (2003). Inequality and growth: Why differential fertility matters. American Economic Review, 93, 10911113.10.1257/000282803769206214CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D., & Doepke, M. (2004). Public versus private education when differential fertility matters. Journal of Development Economics, 73, 607629.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2003.05.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D., & Docquier, F. (2012). Do brain drain and poverty result from coordination failures? Journal of Economic Growth, 17, 126.10.1007/s10887-011-9073-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delogu, M., Docquier, F., & Machado, J. (2018). Globalizing labor and the world economy: The role of human capital. Journal of Economic Growth, 23, 223258.10.1007/s10887-017-9153-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Paola, M., & Brunello, G. (2016). Education as a tool for economic integration of migrants. IZA Discussion Paper No. 9836. Bonn Germany.10.2139/ssrn.2757926CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Docquier, F., Machado, J., & Sekkat, K. (2015). Efficiency gains from liberalizing labor mobility. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 117, 303346.10.1111/sjoe.12097CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Docquier, F., & Marfouk, A. (2006). International migration by education attainment, 1990-2000. In Ozden, C., & Schiff, M. (Eds.), International migration, brain drain and remittances (Chapter 5, pp. 681–730). New York: McMillan and Palgrave.Google Scholar
Docquier, F., & Rapoport, H. (2012). Globalization, brain drain and development. Journal of Economic Literature, 50, 681730.10.1257/jel.50.3.681CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dustmann, C., Frattini, T., & Lanzara, G. (2012). Educational achievements of second-generation immigrants: An intergenerational comparison. Economic Policy, 27, 143165.10.1111/j.1468-0327.2011.00275.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández-Huertas Moraga, J., & Rapoport, H. (2014). Tradable immigration quotas. Journal of Public Economics, 115, 94108.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2014.04.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández-Huertas Moraga, J., & Rapoport, H. (2015). Tradable refugee-admission quotas and EU asylum policy. CESifo Economic Studies, 61, 638672.10.1093/cesifo/ifu037CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. (2012). The demographic transition: Causes and consequences. Cleometrica, 6, 128.10.1007/s11698-011-0062-7CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 11331191.10.1162/003355302320935007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O., & Mountford, A. (2006). Trade and the Great Divergence: The family connection. American Economic Review, 96, 229303.10.1257/000282806777212378CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O., & Mountford, A. (2008). Trading population for productivity: Theory and evidence. Review of Economic Studies, 75, 11431179.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2008.00501.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O., & Tsiddon, D. (1997). The distribution of human capital and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 2, 93124.10.1023/A:1009785714248CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groenendijk, K. (2006). Family reunification as a right under community law. European Journal of Migration and Law, 8, 215230.10.1163/157181606777975003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heath, A.F., Rothon, C., & Kilpi, E. (2008). The second generation in Western Europe: Education, unemployment, and occupational attainment. Annual Review of Sociology, 34, 211235.10.1146/annurev.soc.34.040507.134728CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckmann, U. (2008). Education and migration. Strategies for integrating migrant children in European schools and societies. A synthesis of research findings for policy-makers. NESSE: European Commission.Google Scholar
Honohan, I. (2009). Reconsidering the claim of family reunification in migration. Political Studies, 57, 768787.10.1111/j.1467-9248.2008.00761.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Janta, B., & Harte, E. (2016). Education of migrant children: Education policy responses for the inclusion of migrant children in Europe. Research report. Rand Europe.10.7249/RR1655CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ludemann, E., & Schwerdt, G. (2013). Migration background and educational tracking is there a double disadvantage for second-generation immigrants? Journal of Population Economics, 26, 455481.10.1007/s00148-012-0414-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
McHale, J. (2009). Taxation and skilled Indian migration to the United States: Revisiting the Bhagwati tax. In Bhagwati, J., & Hanson, G.H. (Eds.), Skilled immigration: Problems, prospects and policies (Chapter 12). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Miyagiwa, K. (1991). Scale economies in education and the brain drain problem. International Economic Review, 32, 743759.10.2307/2527117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moav, O. (2005). Cheap children and the persistence of poverty. Economic Journal, 115, 88110.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2004.00961.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mountford, A. (1997). Can a brain drain be good for growth in the source economy? Journal of Development Economics, 53, 287303.10.1016/S0304-3878(97)00021-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mountford, A., & Rapoport, H. (2011). The brain drain and the world distribution of income. Journal of Development Economics, 95, 417.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2009.11.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nielsen, H.S., Rosholm, M., Smith, N., & Husted, L. (2003). The school-to-work transition of 2nd generation immigrants in Denmark. Journal of Population Economics, 16, 755786.10.1007/s00148-003-0164-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riphahn, R.T. (2003). Cohort effects in the educational attainment of second generation immigrants in Germany: An analysis of census data. Journal of Population Economics, 16, 711737.10.1007/s00148-003-0146-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schnepf, S.V. (2007). Immigrants’ educational disadvantage: An examination across ten countries and three surveys. Journal of Population Economics, 20, 527545.10.1007/s00148-006-0102-yCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strasser, E., Kraler, A., Bonjour, S., & Bilger, V. (2009). Doing family: Responses to the constructions of the ‘migrant family’ across Europe. The History of the Family, 14, 165176.10.1016/j.hisfam.2009.02.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R. (1991). Income convergence in an endogenous growth model. Journal of Political Economy, 99, 522540.10.1086/261765CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R. (1996). From decay to growth: A demographic transition to economic growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 20, 12371261.10.1016/0165-1889(95)00898-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R. (2006). Human capital and economic development. Journal of Development Economics, 79, 2672.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.12.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, R., & Cuberes, D. (2020). Equilibrium and A-efficient fertility with increasing returns to population and endogenous mortality, Journal of Demographic Economics, 86, 157182.10.1017/dem.2019.15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, J. (2002). Urbanization, population transition, and growth. Oxford Economic Papers, 54, 91117.10.1093/oep/54.1.91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Azarnert supplementary material

Azarnert supplementary material
Download Azarnert supplementary material(File)
File 106 KB