Hostname: page-component-54dcc4c588-nx7b4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-10-06T08:35:25.899Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Abate, bribe or quit: firms’ decision in the presence of environmental regulation, informality and corruption

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 October 2025

Sarbajit Sengupta
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Politics, Visva-Bharati University, Santiniketan, WB, India
Amit K. Biswas*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Politics, Visva-Bharati University, Santiniketan, WB, India
*
Corresponding author: Amit K. Biswas; Email: amitkumar.biswas@visva-bharati.ac.in

Abstract

Public authorities often enforce pollution abatement through monitoring and penalties. However, monitoring is costly and only a small percentage of firms are monitored. Inspectors may be corrupt and permit evasion for a bribe. For firms in developing countries, it is expensive to enter formally and install costly abatement technologies, which are accessible only to formal firms. This paper studies a framework where firms, depending on abatement cost, the probability of inspection, the likelihood of a corrupt inspector and the bribe, choose whether to organize formally or informally and whether to abate before inspection. Firms that do not abate beforehand are liable to either pay a penalty and abate or close down post-inspection. Greater monitoring and lower abatement costs encourage firms to move towards formal organization, while excessively high penalties may discourage entry.

Information

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Aidt, TS, Hillman, AL and Qijun, LIU (2020) Who takes bribes and how much? Evidence from the China Corruption Conviction Databank. World Development 133, 104985.10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.104985CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arguedas, C (2008) To comply or not to comply? Pollution standard setting under costly monitoring and sanctioning. Environmental and Resource Economics 41, 155168.10.1007/s10640-007-9185-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bento, AM, Miller, N, Mookerjee, M and Severnini, E (2023) Incidental adaptation: The role of non-climate regulations. Environmental and Resource Economics 86, 305343.10.1007/s10640-023-00793-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biswas, AK, Farzanegan, M and Thum, M (2012) Pollution, shadow economy and corruption: Theory and evidence. Ecological Economics 75, 114125.10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.01.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biswas, AK and Thum, M (2017) Corruption, environmental regulation and market entry. Environment and Development Economics 22, 6683.10.1017/S1355770X16000218CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blackman, A (2000) Informal sector pollution control: What policy options do we have? World Development 28, 20672082.10.1016/S0305-750X(00)00072-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brundtland, GH (1987) Brundtland Report: Our Common Future. Report of the World Commission on Environment and Development, United Nations.Google Scholar
Chen, H, Hao, Y, Li, J and Song, X (2018) The impact of environmental regulation, shadow economy, and corruption on environmental quality: Theory and empirical evidence from China. Journal of Cleaner Production 195, 200214.10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.05.206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chichilnisky, G (1994) North-South trade and the global environment. American Economic Review 84, 427434.Google Scholar
Cole, MA (2007) Corruption, income and the environment: An empirical analysis. Ecological Economics 62, 637647.10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.08.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
CPCB (2016) Guidelines for Implementing Liabilities for Environmental Damages Due to Handling & Disposal of Hazardous Waste and Penalty. Shahdara, Delhi: Central Pollution Control Board, Ministry of Environment & Forest, Government of India.Google Scholar
Damania, R (2002) Environmental controls with corrupt bureaucrats. Environment and Development Economics 7, 407427.10.1017/S1355770X02000256CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Soto, H (1989) The Other Path. New York: Harper and Row Publishers Inc.Google Scholar
Elgin, C and Oztunali, O (2014) Pollution and informal economy. Economic Systems 38, 333349.10.1016/j.ecosys.2013.11.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feige, EL (1990) Defining and estimating underground and informal economies: The new institutional economics approach. World Development 18, 9891002.10.1016/0305-750X(90)90081-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goel, RK, Herrala, R and Mazhar, U (2013) Institutional quality and environmental pollution: MENA countries versus the rest of the world. Economic Systems 37, 508521.10.1016/j.ecosys.2013.04.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gray, WB and Shimshack, JP (2011) The effectiveness of environmental monitoring and enforcement: A review of the empirical evidence. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 5, 324.10.1093/reep/req017CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenstone, M and Jack, BK (2013) Envirodevonomics: A research agenda for a young field. NBER Working Paper No. 19426, Cambridge, MA.10.3386/w19426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruber, J (2022) Public Finance and Public Policy, 7th edn. New York: Worth Publishers.Google Scholar
ILO (2025) Informal employment rate. International Labour Organization. Available at https://ilostat.ilo.org/data/snapshots/informal-employment-rate.Google Scholar
Karpoff, JM, Lott, JR, Jr and Wehrly, EW (2005) The reputational penalties for environmental violations: Empirical evidence. The Journal of Law and Economics 48, 653675.10.1086/430806CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Porta, R and Shleifer, A (2008) The unofficial economy and economic development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 39, 275352.10.1353/eca.0.0016CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Porta, R and Shleifer, A (2014) Informality and development. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28, 109126.10.1257/jep.28.3.109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindgren, J (1993) The theory, history, and practice of the bribery-extortion distinction. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 141, 16951740.10.2307/3312572CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loayza, NV (1996) The economics of the informal sector: A simple model and some empirical evidence from Latin America. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 45, 129162.10.1016/S0167-2231(96)00021-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishra, A and Ray, R (2013) Informality and corruption. Bath Papers in International Development and Wellbeing No. 21, Centre for Development Studies.Google Scholar
Nguyen, CP and Nguyen, BQ (2023) Environmental foe or friend: The influence of the shadow economy on forest land. Land Use Policy 1(24), 106456.10.1016/j.landusepol.2022.106456CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olken, BA and Barron, P (2009) The simple economics of extortion: Evidence from trucking in Aceh. Journal of Political Economy 117, 417452.10.1086/599707CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pargal, S, Hettige, H, Singh, M and Wheeler, D (1997) Formal and informal regulation of industrial pollution: Comparative evidence from Indonesia and the United States. The World Bank Economic Review 11, 433450.10.1093/wber/11.3.433CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polinsky, AM and Shavell, S (2001) Corruption and optimal law enforcement. Journal of Public Economics 81, 124.10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00127-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shahbaz, M, Nuta, AC, Mishra, P and Ayad, H (2023) The impact of informality and institutional quality on environmental footprint: The case of emerging economies in a comparative approach. Journal of Environmental Management 348, 119325.10.1016/j.jenvman.2023.119325CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shiraguppi, S (2025) Delhi NCR emerges as hotspot for traffic enforcement bribes, survey finds. Autocar Professional,. Available at https://www.autocarpro.in/news/delhi-ncr-emerges-as-hotspot-for-traffic-enforcement-bribes-survey-finds-125014.Google Scholar
Spulber, DF (1985) Effluent regulation and long-run optimality. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 12, 103116.10.1016/0095-0696(85)90021-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Straub, S (2005) Informal sector: The credit market channel. Journal of Development Economics 78, 299321.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.09.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
US Environmental Protection Agency (2010) Regulatory and non-regulatory approaches to pollution control. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analysis, Chapter 4, Ee-0568-04. Washington, D.C.: National Center for Environmental Economics, Office of Policy, US Environmental Protection Agency.Google Scholar
Wade, R (1982) The system of administrative and political corruption: Canal irrigation in South India. Journal of Development Studies 18, 287328.10.1080/00220388208421833CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Welsch, H (2004) Corruption, growth, and the environment: A cross-country analysis. Environment and Development Economics 9, 663693.10.1017/S1355770X04001500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiengarten, F, Singh, PJ, Fynes, B and Nazarpour, A (2017) Impact of mass customization on cost and flexibility performances: The role of social capital. Operations Management Research 10, 137147.10.1007/s12063-017-0127-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar