Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cb9f654ff-w5vf4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-08-21T06:24:01.737Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 June 2025

Matthew Dimick
Affiliation:
University of Buffalo School of Law
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'

Information

Type
Chapter
Information
Ending Income Inequality
A Critical Approach to the Law and Economics of Redistribution
, pp. 325 - 340
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2025

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Book purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Acemoglu, Daron. 2001. “Good Jobs versus Bad Jobs.” Journal of Labor Economics 19 (1): 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robert, Shimer. 1999. “Efficient Unemployment Insurance.” Journal of Political Economy 107 (5): 893928.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ackerman, Bruce. 1971. “Regulating Slum Housing Markets on Behalf of the Poor: Of Housing Codes, Housing Subsidies and Income Redistribution Policy.” Yale Law Journal 80 (6): 109397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. 2012. Well-Being and Fair Distribution: Beyond Cost-Benefit Analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. and Posner, Eric A.. 1999. “Rethinking Cost-Benefit Analysis.” Yale Law Journal 109 (2): 165247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, Matthew D., and Chris William Sanchirico. 2006. “Inequality and Uncertainty: Theory and Legal Applications.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review 155 (2): 279377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, Philippe, Akcigit, Ufuk, Bergeaud, Antonin, Blundell, Richard, and Hémous, David. 2019. “Innovation and Top Income Inequality.” Review of Economic Studies 86 (1): 145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Stephen P. 1987. “Taxes, Redistribution, and the Minimum Wage: A Theoretical Analysis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (3): 47789.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Richard M., Kearl, James R., and Vaughan, Michael B.. 1992. “Is There a Consensus among Economists in the 1990’s?American Economic Review 82 (2): 20309.Google Scholar
Alstott, Anne L. 1999. “Work vs. Freedom: A Liberal Challenge to Employment Subsidies.” Yale Law Journal 108 (5): 9671058.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvaredo, Facundo. 2011. “A Note on the Relationship between Top Income Shares and the Gini Coefficient.” Economics Letters 110 (3): 27477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Appelbaum, Benyamin. 2017. “This Is Not Arthur Laffer’s Famous Napkin.” The New York Times (October 13, 2017). Accessed March 22, 2024. www.nytimes.com/2017/10/13/us/politics/arthur-laffer-napkin-tax-curve.html.Google Scholar
Arlen, Jennifer H. 1992. “Should Defendants’ Wealth Matter?Journal of Legal Studies 21 (2): 41329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnott, Richard. 1995. “Time for Revisionism on Rent Control?Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (1): 99120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnott, Richard, and Igarashi, Masahiro. 2000. “Rent Control, Mismatch Costs and Search Efficiency.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 30 (3): 24988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 2012 [1951]. Social Choice and Individual Values. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Atkinson, Anthony B. 1970. “On the Measurement of Inequality.” Journal of Economic Theory 2 (3): 24463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, Anthony B., and Stiglitz, Joseph E.. 1976. “The Design of Tax Structure: Direct versus Indirect Taxation.” Journal of Public Economics 6 (1-2): 5575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, Anthony B., and Stiglitz, Joseph E.. 2015. Lectures on Public Economics. Updated edition. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Autor, David H., Dorn, David, and Hanson, Gordon H.. 2013. “The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States.” American Economic Review 103 (6): 212168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, David H., Manning, Alan, and Smith, Christopher L.. 2016. “The Contribution of the MinimumWage to US Wage Inequality over Three Decades: A Reassessment.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 8 (1): 5899.Google Scholar
Autor, David H., Palmer, Christopher J., and Pathak, Parag A.. 2014. “Housing Market Spillovers: Evidence from the End of Rent Control in Cambridge, Massachusetts.” Journal of Political Economy 122 (3): 661717.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Averitt, Neil W., and Lande, Robert H.. 2007. “Using the Consumer Choice Approach to Antitrust Law.” Antitrust Law Journal 74 (1): 175264.Google Scholar
Avraham, Ronen, Fortus, David, and Logue, Kyle. 2003. “Revisiting the Roles of Legal Rules and Tax Rules in Income Redistribution: A Response to Kaplow & Shavell.” Iowa Law Review 89 (4): 1125.Google Scholar
Ayer, A. J. 1971 [1936] Language, Truth and Logic. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian. 2007. “Market Power and Inequality: A Competitive Conduct Standard for Assessing When Disparate Impacts Are Unjustified.” California Law Review 95 (3): 669720.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian, and Gertner, Robert. 1989. “Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules.” Yale Law Journal 99 (1): 87130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Ian, and Talley, Eric. 1995. “Solomonic Bargaining: Dividing a Legal Entitlement to Facilitate Coasean Trade.” Yale Law Journal 104 (5): 1027117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, C. Edwin. 1975. “The Ideology of the Economic Analysis of Law.” Philosophy & Public Affairs 5 (1): 348.Google Scholar
Baker, Dean. 2020a. “A World With a $24 Minimum Wage.” Jacobin. January 27. https://jacobinmag.com/2020/01/higher-minimum-wage-inflation-productivity.Google Scholar
2020b. This Is What Minimum Wage Would Be If It Kept Pace with Productivity, January. https://cepr.net/publications/correction-this-is-what-minimum-wage-would-be-if-it-kept-pace-with-productivity/.Google Scholar
Bankman, Joseph, and Griffith, Thomas. 1987. “Social Welfare and the Rate Structure: A New Look at Progressive Taxation.” California Law Review 75: 1905.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, Brian. 1986. “Lady Chatterly's Lover and Doctor Fischer's Bomb Party: Liberalism, Pareto Optimality, and the Problem of Objectionable Preferences.” In Foundations of Social Choice Theory, edited by Elster, Jon and Hylland, Aanund, 1143. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, Lucian Ayre, and Shavell, Steven. 1991. “Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale.” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 7 (2): 284312.Google Scholar
Belli, Melvin M. 1951. “The Adequate Award.” California Law Review 39 (1): 141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bentham, Jeremy. 1843. “Anarchical Fallacies; Being an Examination of the Declarations of Rights Issued during the French Revolution.” In Works of Jeremy Bentham, edited by Bowring, John, II:489534. Edinburgh: William Tait.Google Scholar
Berliner, Dana. 2006. Opening the Floodgates: Eminent Domain Abuse in the Post Kelo World. Arlington, VA: Institute for Justice.Google Scholar
Bhaskar, Venkataraman, Manning, Alan, and To, Ted. 2002. “Oligopsony and Monopsonistic Competition in Labor Markets.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (2): 15574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhaskar, Venkataraman, and To, Ted. 1999. “Minimum Wages for Ronald McDonald Monopsonies: A Theory of Monopsonistic Competition.” Economic Journal 109 (455): 190203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Ken. 2009. “Interpersonal Comparison of Utility.” In Oxford Handbook of Philosophy of Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Blumkin, Tomer, and Margalioth, Yoram. 2005. “On the Limits of Redistributive Taxation: Establishing a Case for Equity-Informed Legal Rules.” Virginia Tax Review 25 (1): 129.Google Scholar
Blumkin, Tomer, and Sadka, Efraim. 2005. “Income Taxation and Wage Policy: An Application to Minimum Wage.” International Tax and Public Finance 12 (6): 71322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blundell, Richard, and MaCurdy, Thomas. 1999. “Labor Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches.” In Handbook of Labour Economics, edited by Ashenfelter, Orley and Card, David, vol. 3A, 1559695. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin. 1997. “Public Economics and the Theory of Public Policy.” Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d’economique 30 (4a): 75372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, Robin, and Cuff, Katherine. 2001. “A Minimum Wage Can Be Welfare-Improving and Employment-Enhancing.” European Economic Review 45 (3): 55376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boal, William M., and Ransom, Michael R.. 1997. “Monopsony in the Labor Market.” Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1): 86112.Google Scholar
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (US). 2023a. “Share of Corporate Equities and Mutual Fund Shares Held by the 90th to 99thWealth Percentiles [WFRBSN09149].” Retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/WFRBSN09149. Accessed December 27, 2023.Google Scholar
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (US). 2023b. “Share of Corporate Equities and Mutual Fund Shares Held by the Top 1% (99th to 100th Wealth Percentiles) [WFRBST01122].” Retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/WFRBST01122. Accessed December 27, 2023.Google Scholar
Borjas, George J. 2016. Labor Economics. 7th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Education.Google Scholar
Bork, Robert H. 1967. “The Goals of Antitrust Policy.” American Economic Review 57 (2): 24253.Google Scholar
Bork, Robert H. 1978. The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Boudette, Neal E. 2024. “VW Workers in Tennessee Vote for Union, a Labor Milestone.” The New York Times (April 19, 2024). Accessed May 8, 2024. www.nytimes.com/2024/04/19/business/economy/volkswagen-united-automobile-workers-union.html.Google Scholar
Bronars, Stephen G., Deere, Donald R., and Tracy, Joseph S.. 1994. “The Effects of Unions on Firm Behavior: An Empirical Analysis Using Firm-Level Data.” Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 33 (4): 42651.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruenig, Matt. 2023. The Starbucks Union Has Now Won 300 Elections. People's Policy Project. www.peoplespolicyproject.org/2023/05/11/the-starbucks-union-hasnow-won-300-elections/.Google Scholar
Burdett, Kenneth, and Mortensen, Dale T.. 1998. “Wage Differentials, Employer Size, and Unemployment.” International Economic Review, 39 (2): 25773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burke, Marcilynn. 2006. “Much Ado about Nothing: Kelo v. City of New London, Babbitt v. Sweet Home, and Other Tales from the Supreme Court.” University of Cincinnati Law Review 75 (2): 663723.Google Scholar
Cahuc, Pierre, and Laroque, Guy. 2014. “Optimal Taxation and Monopsonistic Labor Market: Does Monopsony Justify the Minimum Wage?Journal of Public Economic Theory 16 (2): 25973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cahuc, Pierre, Saint-Martin, Anne, and Zylberberg, André. 2001. “The Consequences of the Minimum Wage When Other Wages Are Bargained Over.” European Economic Review 45 (2): 33752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1991. “The Pointlessness of Pareto: Carrying Coase Further.” Yale Law Journal 100 (5): 1211237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 2016. The Future of Law and Economics: Essays in Reform and Recollection. New Haven: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, Guido, and Melamed, A. Douglas. 1972. “Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral.” Harvard Law Review, 85 (6): 1089128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calmfors, Lars, and Driffill, John. 1988. “Bargaining Structure, Corporatism and Macroeconomic Performance.” Economic Policy 3 (6): 1361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, David. 2001. “The Effect of Unions on Wage Inequality in the US Labor Market.” ILR Review 54 (2): 296315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, David, and Krueger, Alan B.. 1994. “Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania.” American Economic Review 84 (4): 77293.Google Scholar
Card, David, and Krueger, Alan B.. 2000. “Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania: Reply.” American Economic Review 90 (5): 1397420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, David, and Krueger, Alan B.. 2015. Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage. Twentieth-Anniversary Edition. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, Dick M. II, and Ross, John K.. 2007. Victimizing the Vulnerable: The Demographics of Eminent Domain Abuse. Arlington, VA: Institute for Justice.Google Scholar
Cassidy, John. 2008. “Comment: The Minsky Moment.” The New Yorker 83 (46): 19.Google Scholar
Cesarini, David, Lindqvist, Erik, Notowidigdo, Matthew J, and Östling, Robert. 2017. “The Effect of Wealth on Individual and Household Labor Supply: Evidence from Swedish Lotteries.” American Economic Review 107 (12): 391746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamley, Christophe. 1986. “Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with Infinite Lives.” Econometrica, 54 (3): 60722.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chimerine, Lawrence, and Eisenbrey, Ross. 2005. The Frivolous Case for Tort Law Change. Economic Policy Institute. https://files.epi.org/page/-/old/briefingpapers/157/bp157.pdf.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law & Economics 3:144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, Jules L. 1980. “Efficiency, Utility, and Wealth Maximization.” Hofstra Law Review 8:50951.Google Scholar
Colvin, Alexander J. S. 2014. “Mandatory Arbitration and Inequality of Justice in Employment.” Berkeley Journal of Employment and Labor Law 35 (1-2): 7190.Google Scholar
Colvin, Alexander J. S. 2017. The Growing Use of Mandatory Arbitration. Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institue, September 27, 2017. http://epi.org/135056.Google Scholar
Colvin, Alexander, J. S., and Gough, Mark D.. 2015. “Individual Employment Rights Arbitration in the United States: Actors and Outcomes.” ILR Review 68 (5): 1019042.Google Scholar
Congressional Budget Office. 2004. The Effects of Tort Reform: Evidence from the States. Washington, DC. www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/108th-congress-2003-2004/reports/report_2.pdf.Google Scholar
Connolly, Robert A., Hirsch, Barry T., and Hirschey, Mark. 1986. “Union Rent Seeking, Intangible Capital, and Market Value of the Firm.” Review of Economics and Statistics 68 (4): 56777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooter, Robert, and Ulen, Thomas. 2016. Law and Economics. 6th ed. Boston: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Craswell, Richard. 1991. “Passing on the Costs of Legal Rules: Efficiency and Distribution in Buyer-Seller Relationships.” Stanford Law Review 43 (2): 36198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Craswell, Richard. 2003. “Kaplow and Shavell on the Substance of Fairness.” Journal of Legal Studies 32 (1): 24575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson, Donald. 1986. “Judging Interpersonal Interests.” In Foundations of Social Choice Theory, edited by Elster, Jon and Hylland, Aanund, 195211. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
De Scitovszky, Tibor. 1941. “A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics.” Review of Economic Studies 9 (1): 7788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deb, Shubhdeep, Eeckhout, Jan, Patel, Aseem, and Warren, Lawrence. 2022. “What Drives Wage Stagnation: Monopsony or Monopoly?Journal of the European Economic Association 20 (6): 2181225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denny, Kevin, and Nickell, Stephen J.. 1992. “Unions and Investment in British Industry.” Economic Journal 102 (413): 87487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Peter A. 1980. “Income Taxation with Fixed Hours of Work.” Journal of Public Economics 13 (1): 10110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Peter A. 1982. “Wage Determination and Efficiency in Search Equilibrium.” Review of Economic Studies 49 (2): 21727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Peter A., and Saez, Emmanuel. 2011. “The Case for a Progressive Tax: From Basic Research to Policy Recommendation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 (4): 16590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Rebecca, McQuade, Tim, and Qian, Franklin. 2019. “The Effects of Rent Control Expansion on Tenants, Landlords, and Inequality: Evidence from San Francisco.” American Economic Review 109 (9): 336594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiCola, Peter C. 2013. “Money from Music: Survey Evidence on Musicians' Revenue and Lessons about Copyright Incentives.” Arizona Law Review 55 (2): 30170.Google Scholar
Dimick, Matthew. 2019. “The Law and Economics of Redistribution.” Annual Review of Law & Social Science 15:55982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiNardo, John, Fortin, Nicole M., and Lemieux, Thomas. 1996. “Labor Market Institutions and the Distribution of Wages, 1973–1992: A Semiparametric Approach.” Econometrica 64 (5): 1001044.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Disney, Richard, and Gathergood, John. 2018. “House Prices, Wealth Effects and Labour Supply.” Economica 85 (339): 44978.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash K., and Stiglitz, Joseph E.. 1977. “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity.” American Economic Review 67 (3): 297308.Google Scholar
Dorff, Michael B. 2001. “Why Welfare Depends on Fairness: A Reply to Kaplow and Shavell.” Southern California Law Review 75 (4): 847.Google Scholar
Drazen, Allan. 1986. “Optimal MinimumWage Legislation.” Economic Journal 96 (383): 77484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dube, Arindrajit. 2019. “Minimum Wages and the Distribution of Family Incomes.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 11 (4): 268304.Google Scholar
Dube, Arindrajit, William Lester, T., and Reich, Michael. 2016. “Minimum Wage Shocks, Employment Flows, and Labor Market Frictions.” Journal of Labor Economics 34 (3): 663704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunlop, John T. 1944. Wage Determination under Trade Unions. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Dworkin, Ronald M. 1980. “Is Wealth a Value?Journal of Legal Studies 9 (2): 191226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, Jonathan, and Rosen, Harvey S.. 1980. “Optimal Redistributive Taxation and Uncertainty.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 95 (2): 35764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. 1897. “The Pure Theory of Taxation.” Economic Journal 7 (28): 55071.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisenberg, Theodore. 2015. “Four Decades of Federal Civil Rights Litigation.” Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 12 (1): 428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. 1991. Order without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engbom, Niklas, and Moser, Christian. 2022. “Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil.” American Economic Review 112 (12): 380347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enghagen, Linda K., and Gilardi, Anthony. 2002. “Putting Things in Perspective: McDonald's and the 2.9-Million Dollar Cup of Coffee.” Cornell Hotel & Restaurant Administration Quarterly 43 (3): 5360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1975. “Unconscionability: A Critical Reappraisal.” Journal of Law and Economics 18 (2): 293315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1983. “A Common Law for Labor Relations: A Critique of the New Deal Labor Legislation.” Yale Law Journal 92 (8): 1357408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
2015. “Kelo v. City of New London Ten Years Later.” National Review (June 23, 2015). Accessed June 23, 2015. www.nationalreview.com/2015/06/kelo-eminent-domain-richard-epstein/.Google Scholar
Eriksen, Michael D., and Ross, Amanda. 2015. “Housing Vouchers and the Price of Rental Housing.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7 (3): 54176.Google Scholar
Estlund, Cynthia. 2018. “The Black Hole of Mandatory Arbitration.” North Carolina Law Review 96 (3): 679710.Google Scholar
Fennell, Lee Anne, and McAdams, Richard H.. 2016. “The Distributive Deficit in Law and Economics.” Minnesota Law Review 100 (3): 1051129.Google Scholar
Fleischer, Victor. 2015. “Curb Your Enthusiasm for Pigovian Taxes.” Vanderbilt Law Review 68 (6): 1673713.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil, and Goldstein, Adam. 2012. “A Long Strange Trip: The State and Mortgage Securitization, 1968-2010.” In Oxford Handbook of the Sociology of Finance, edited by Knorr Cetina, Karin and Preda, Alex, 33956. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Flinn, Christopher J. 2006. “Minimum Wage Effects on Labor Market Outcomes under Search, Matching, and Endogenous Contact Rates.” Econometrica 74 (4): 101362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Richard B. 1980. “Unionism and the Dispersion of Wages.” ILR Review 34 (1): 323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Richard B. and Medoff, James. 1981. “The Impact of the Percentage Organized on Union and Nonunion Wages.” Review of Economics and Statistics 63 (4): 56172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gabuthy, Yannick, and Lambert, Eve-Angéline. 2018. “Legal Advertising and Frivolous Lawsuits.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 174 (3): 57093.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallini, Nancy T. 2002. “The Economics of Patents: Lessons from Recent US Patent Reform.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (2): 13154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gamage, David. 2014. “How Should Governments Promote Distributive Justice?: A Framework for Analyzing the Optimal Choice of Tax Instruments.” Tax Law Review 68 (1): 187.Google Scholar
Gamage, David. 2015. “The Case for Taxing (All of) Labor Income, Consumption, Capital Income, and Wealth.” Tax Law Review 68:355441.Google Scholar
Gates, Bill, Myhrvold, Nathan, and Rinearson, Peter. 1995. The Road Ahead. New York: Viking Press.Google Scholar
Greenberg, David. 1980. “Easy Terms, Hard Times: Complaint Handling in the Ghetto.” In No Access to Law: Alternatives to the American Judicial System, edited by Nader, Laura, 379415. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Greenspan, Alan. 2005. Remarks by Chairman Alan Greenspan. At the Federal Reserve System's Fourth Annual Community Affairs Research Conference, Washington, D.C. April 8, 2005. Accessed November 25, 2023. www.federalreserve.gov/BoardDocs/speeches/2005/20050408/default.htm.Google Scholar
Grout, Paul A. 1984. “Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach.” Econometrica 52 (2): 44960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grullon, Gustavo, Larkin, Yelena, and Michaely, Roni. 2019. “Are US Industries Becoming More Concentrated?Review of Finance 23 (4): 697743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guesnerie, Roger, and Roberts, Kevin. 1987. “Minimum Wage Legislation as a Second Best Policy.” European Economic Review 31 (1-2): 49098.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob. 2011. “The Institutional Foundations of Middle-Class Democracy.” Policy Network 6 (5): 3337.Google Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1923. “Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State.” Political Science Quarterly 38 (3): 470494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1943. “Bargaining, Duress, and Economic Liberty.” Columbia Law Review 43 (5): 60328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamada, Koichi. 1976. “Liability Rules and Income Distribution in Product Liability.” American Economic Review 66 (1): 22834.Google Scholar
Hammond, Peter J. 1991. “Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility: Why and How They Are and Should Be Made.” In Interpersonal Comparisons of Well-Being, edited by Elster, Jon and Roemer, John E., 20054. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanlon, James. 2017. “The Origins of the Rental Assistance Demonstration Program and the End of Public Housing.” Housing Policy Debate 27 (4): 61139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hasen, David. 2006. “Liberalism and Ability Taxation.” Texas Law Review 85 (5): 1057.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel M. 1995. “The Impossibility of Interpersonal Utility Comparisons.” Mind 104 (415): 47390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas A. Jr., and Locking, Håkan. 2000. “Wage Dispersion and Productive Efficiency: Evidence for Sweden.” Journal of Labor Economics 18 (4): 75582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1939. “The Foundations of Welfare Economics.” Economic Journal 49 (196): 696712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hindriks, Jean, and Myles, Gareth D. 2013. Intermediate Public Economics. 2nd ed. MIT Press. Hirsch, Barry T.Google Scholar
Hindriks, Jean, and Myles, Gareth D. 1992. “Firm Investment Behavior and Collective Bargaining Strategy.” Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 31 (1): 95121.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Werner Z., Hirsch, Joel G., and Margolis, Stephen. 1975. “Regression Analysis of the Effects of Habitability Laws upon Rent: An Empirical Observation on the Ackerman- Komesar Debate.” California Law Review 63 (5): 1098.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosios, Arthur J. 1990. “On the Efficiency of Matching and Related Models of Search and Unemployment.” Review of Economic Studies 57 (2): 27998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 2016. “Appraising Merger Efficiencies.” George Mason Law Review 24 (3): 70341.Google Scholar
Hua, Xinyu, and Spier, Kathryn E.. 2020. “Product Safety, Contracts, and Liability.” RAND Journal of Economics 51 (1): 23359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubbard, F. Patrick. 2006. “The Nature and Impact of the ‘Tort Reform' Movement.” Hofstra Law Review 35 (2): 437538.Google Scholar
Hughes, Justin, and Merges, Robert P.. 2016. “Copyright and Distributive Justice.” Notre Dame Law Review 92 (2): 513.Google Scholar
Mathias, Hungerbühler, and Lehmann, Etienne. 2009. “On the Optimality of a Minimum Wage: New Insights from Optimal Tax Theory.” Journal of Public Economics 93 (3): 46481.Google Scholar
Hurst, Nathan. 2013. “How the America Invents Act Will Change Patenting Forever.” Wired Magazine (March 13, 2013). Accessed March 13, 2013. www.wired.com/2013/03/america-invents-act/.Google Scholar
Hylland, Aanund, and Zeckhauser, Richard. 1979. “Distributional Objectives Should Affect Taxes but Not Program Choice or Design.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 81 (2): 26484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hylton, Keith N. 2013. “The Law and Economics of Products Liability.” Notre Dame Law Review 88 (5): 2457514.Google Scholar
Irwin, Neil. 2016. “A New Movement in Liberal Economics That Could Shape Hillary Clinton's Agenda.” The New York Times (November 4, 2016). Accessed March 22, 2024. www.nytimes.com/2o16/11/o6/upshot/monopsony-liberal-economics-policyhillary-clintons-agenda.html.Google Scholar
Jaffe, Adam B. 2000. “The US Patent System in Transition: Policy Innovation and the Innovation Process.” Research Policy 29 (4-5): 31557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnston, Jason Scott. 1990. “Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules.” Yale Law Journal 100 (3): 61564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jolls, Christine. 1998. “Behavioral Economics Analysis of Redistributive Legal Rules.” Vanderbilt Law Review 51 (6): 1653.Google Scholar
Jones, Stephen R. G. 1987. “Minimum Wage Legislation in a Dual Labor Market.” European Economic Review 31 (6): 1229246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, Kenneth L. 1985. “Redistributive Taxation in a Simple Perfect Foresight Model.” Journal of Public Economics 28 (1): 5983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kakwani, Nanak C. 1977a. “Applications of Lorenz Curves in Economic Analysis.” Econometrica 45 (3): 71927.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kakwani, Nanak C. 1977b. “Measurement of Tax Progressivity: An International Comparison.” Economic Journal 87 (345): 7180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1939. “Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility.” Economic Journal, 49 (195): 54952.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kang, Cecilia. 2023. “F.T.C.'s Court Loss Raises Fresh Questions about Its Chair's Strategy.” The New York Times (July 11,2023). Accessed December 26, 2023. www.nytimes.com/2023/07/11/technology/lina-khan-ftc-strategy.html?searchResultPosition=7.Google Scholar
Kantor, Jodi, and Weise, Karen. 2022. “How Two Best Friends Beat Amazon.” The New York Times (April 14, 2022). Accessed May 8, 2024. www.nytimes.com/2022/04/02/business/amazon-union-christian-smalls.html.Google Scholar
Kapczynski, Amy. 2011. “The Cost of Price: Why and How to Get beyond Intellectual Property Internalism.” UCLA Law Review 59 (4): 970.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 1995. “A Fundamental Objection to Tax Equity Norms: A Call for Utilitarianism.” National Tax Journal 48 (4): 497514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 1996. “The Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation.” National Tax Journal 49 (4): 51333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 2004. “On the (Ir)relevance of Distribution and Labor Supply Distortion to Government Policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (4): 15975.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 2006. “On the Undesirability of Commodity Taxation Even When Income Taxation Is Not Optimal.” Journal of Public Economics 90 (6): 123550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 2008. The Theory of Taxation and Public Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 2012. “On the Choice of Welfare Standards in Competition Law.” In The Goals of Competition Law, edited by Daniel Zimmer, 3-26. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 2021. “Market Power and Income Taxation.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 13 (4): 32954.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven. 1994. “Why the Legal System Is Less Efficient Than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income.” Journal of Legal Studies 23 (2): 66781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven. 1999. “The Conflict between Notions of Fairness and the Pareto Principle.” American Law and Economics Review 1 (1): 6377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven. 2000a. “Notions of Fairness versus the Pareto Principle: On the Role of Logical Consistency.” Yale Law Journal 110 (2): 23749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven. 2000b. “Should Legal Rules Favor the Poor? Clarifying the Role of Legal Rules and the Income Tax in Redistributing Income.” Journal of Legal Studies 29 (2): 82135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven. 2001a. “Any Non-Welfarist Method of Policy Assessment Violates the Pareto Principle.” Journal of Political Economy 109 (2): 28186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven. 2001b. “Fairness versus Welfare.” Harvard Law Review 114 (4): 9611388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven. 2002. Fairness versus Welfare. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven. 2003. “Fairness versus Welfare: Notes on the Pareto Principle, Preferences, and Distributive Justice.” Journal of Legal Studies 32 (1): 33162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, Michael L. 1984. “Price Discrimination and Monopolistic Competition.” Econometrica 52 (6): 145371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kazis, Noah M. 2022. “The Failed Federalism of Affordable Housing: Why States Don't Use Housing Vouchers.” Michigan Law Review 121 (2): 22189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelman, Mark. 1987. A Guide to Critical Legal Studies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1981. “Distributive and Paternalist Motives in Contract and Tort Law, with Special Reference to Compulsory Terms and Unequal Bargaining Power.” Maryland Law Review 41 (4): 563658.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1987. “The Effect of the Warranty of Habitability on Low Income Housing: ‘Milking' and Class Violence.” Forida State University Law Review 15 (3): 485519.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1991. “The Stakes of Law, or Hale and Foucault!Legal Studies Forum 15 (4): 327.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1998. “Law and Economics from the Perspective of Critical Legal Studies.” In New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, edited by Newman, Peter, 2:46574. New York: Stockton Press.Google Scholar
Khan, Lina M. 2016. “Amazon's Antitrust Paradox.” Yale Law Journal 126 (3): 710805.Google Scholar
Klock, Mark. 2002. “Unconscionability and Price Discrimination.” Tennessee Law Review 69:317.Google Scholar
Komesar, Neil K. 1973. “Return to Slumville: A Critique of the Ackerman Analysis of Housing Code Enforcement and the Poor.” Yale Law Journal 82 (6): 117593.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Komesar, Neil K. 1983. “Revolution in Landlord-Tenant Law: A Comparative Institutional View.” Cornell Law Review 69 (3): 61222.Google Scholar
Kornhauser, Lewis A. 2003. “Preference, Well-Being, and Morality in Social Decisions.” Journal of Legal Studies 32 (1): 30329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuziemko, Ilyana, Marx, Nicolas Longuet, and Naidu, Suresh. 2023. “Compensate the Losers?” Economic Policy and Partisan Realignment in the US. Working Paper Series 31794. National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w31794.www.nber.org/papers/w31794%22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kwoka, John E. 2017. U.S. Antitrust and Competition Policy amid the New Merger Wave. Washington, DC: Washington Center for Equitable Growth. https://equitablegrowth.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/07/072717-kwoka-antitrust-report.pdf.Google Scholar
Lambert, Peter. 2001. The Distribution and Redistribution of Income. 3rd. ed. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Lande, Robert H. 1982. “Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged.” Hastings Law Journal 34 (1): 65151.Google Scholar
Lande, Robert H. 1989. “Chicago's False Foundation: Wealth Transfers (Not Just Efficiency) Should Guide Antitrust.” Antitrust Law Journal 58 (2): 63144.Google Scholar
Lang, Kevin. 1987. “Pareto Improving Minimum Wage Laws.” Economic Inquiry 25 (1): 14558.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, David. 1999. “Wage Inequality in the United States during the 1980s: Rising Dispersion or Falling Minimum Wage?Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3): 9771023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, David, and Saez, Emmanuel. 2008. Optimal Minimum Wage Policy in Competitive Labor Markets. Working Paper Series 14320. National Bureau of Economic Research. doi.org/10.3386/w14320. www.nber.org/papers/w14320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, David, and Saez, Emmanuel. 2012. “Optimal Minimum Wage Policy in Competitive Labor Markets.” Journal of Public Economics 96 (9): 73949.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Emery G. III, and Willging, Thomas E.. 2008. The Impact of the Class Action Fairness Act of 2005 on the Federal Courts. Washington, DC: Federal Judicial Center, April 1, 2008. www.fjc.gov/content/impact-class-action-fairness-act-2005-federalcourts-fourth-interim-report-judicial-0.Google Scholar
Lewinsohn-Zamir, Daphna. 2006. “In Defense of Redistribution through Private Law.” Minnesota Law Review 91 (2): 32697.Google Scholar
Lin, Ken-Hou, and Tomaskovic-Devey, Donald. 2013. “Financialization and US Income Inequality, 1970-2008.” American Journal of Sociology 118 (5): 12841329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., and Lancaster, Kelvin. 1956. “The General Theory of Second Best.” Review of Economic Studies 24 (1): 1132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liscow, Zachary. 2014. “Reducing Inequality on the Cheap: When Legal Rule Design Should Incorporate Equity as Well as Efficiency.” Yale Law Journal 123 (7): 2478510.Google Scholar
Liscow, Zachary. 2018. “Is Efficiency Biased?University of Chicago Law Review 85 (7): 1649.Google Scholar
Litman, Jessica. 2010. “Real Copyright Reform.” Iowa Law Review 96 (1): 155.Google Scholar
Little, I. M. D. 1952. “Social Choice and Individual Values.” Journal of Political Economy 60 (5): 42232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manning, Alan. 1987. “An Integration of Trade Union Models in a Sequential Bargaining Framework.” Economic Journal 97 (385): 12139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manning, Alan. 2004. “Monopsony and the Efficiency of Labour Market Interventions.” Labour Economics 11 (2): 14563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manning, Alan. 2021. “Monopsony in Labor Markets: A Review.” ILR Review 74 (1): 326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marinescu, Ioana, and Hovenkamp, Herbert. 2019. “Anticompetitive Mergers in Labor Markets.” Indiana Law Journal 94 (3): 103163.Google Scholar
Markovits, Richard S. 1976. “The Distributive Impact, Allocative Efficiency, and Overall Desirability of Ideal Housing Codes: Some Theoretical Clarifications.” Harvard Law Review, 89 (8): 181546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markovits, Richard S. 1980. “Legal Analysis and the Economic Analysis of Allocative Efficiency.” Hofstra Law Review 8 (4): 811903.Google Scholar
Markovits, Richard S. 2004. “Why Kaplow and Shavell's Double-Distortion Argument Articles Are Wrong.” George Mason Law Review 13 (3): 511619.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, Andreu, Michael D. Whinston, and Green, Jerry R.. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mason, J. W. 2019. “Why Rent Control Works.” Jacobin. November 26. https://jacobin.com/2019/11/rent-controlhousing-crisis-affordability-supply.Google Scholar
McAfee, R. Preston, Mialon, Hugo M., and Williams, Michael A.. 2004. “What Is a Barrier to Entry?American Economic Review 94 (2): 46165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCaffery, Edward J. 2005. “A New Understanding of Tax.” Michigan Law Review 103 (5): 807938.Google Scholar
McDonald, Ian M., and Solow, Robert M.. 1981. “Wage Bargaining and Employment.” American Economic Review 71 (5): 896908.Google Scholar
Menezes-Filho, Naercio, and Van Reenen, John. 2003. “Unions and Innovation: A Survey of the Theory and Empirical Evidence.” In International Handbook of Trade Unions, edited by Addison, John T and Schnabel, Claus, 293335. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Merges, Robert P., and Nelson, Richard R.. 1990. “On the Complex Economics of Patent Scope.” Columbia Law Review 90 (4): 839916.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merkel, Philip L. 2006. “Pain and Suffering Damages at Mid-Twentieth Century: A Retrospective View of the Problem and the Legal Academy's First Responses.” Capital University Law Review 34 (3): 54580.Google Scholar
Mian, Atif, and Sufi, Amir. 2009. “The Consequences of Mortgage Credit Expansion: Evidence from the US Mortgage Default Crisis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 144996.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mian, Atif, and Sufi, Amir. 2010. “The Great Recession: Lessons from Microeconomic Data.” American Economic Review 100 (2): 5156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mian, Atif, and Sufi, Amir. 2011. “House Prices, Home Equity-Based Borrowing, and the US Household Leverage Crisis.” American Economic Review 101 (5): 213256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minsky, Hyman P. 1986. Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mirrlees, James A. 1971. “An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation.” Review of Economic Studies 38 (2): 175208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, James A. 1990. “Taxing Uncertain Incomes.” Oxford Economic Papers 42 (1): 3445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moen, Espen R. 1997. “Competitive Search Equilibrium.” Journal of Political Economy 105 (2): 385411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moene, Karl Ove, and Wallerstein, Michael. 1997. “Pay Inequality.” Journal of Labor Economics 15 (3): 40330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, James D. 1991. “Equilibrium Wage Dispersion and Interindustry Wage Differentials.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (1): 16379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mortensen, Dale T. 1982. “Property Rights and Efficiency in Mating, Racing, and Related Games.” American Economic Review 72 (5): 96879.Google Scholar
Mortensen, Dale T., and Pissarides, Christopher A.. 1999. “New Developments in Models of Search in the Labor Market.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, edited by Ashenfelter, Orley and Card, David E., 3B: 2567627. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Murphy, Liam, and Nagel, Thomas. 2002. The Myth of Ownership: Taxes and Justice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Musgrave, Richard A. 1959. The Theory of Public Finance: A Study in Public Economy. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Musgrave, Richard A., and Thin, Tun. 1948. “Income Tax Progression, 1929-48.” Journal of Political Economy 56 (6): 498514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, Thomas. 1986. The View from Nowhere. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Naidu, Suresh, Posner, Eric A., and Weyl, Glen. 2018. “Antitrust Remedies for Labor Market Power.” Harvard Law Review 132 (2): 536601.Google Scholar
Nelson, Katie. 2009. “Conn. Land Taken from Homeowners Still Undeveloped.” Associated Press (September 25, 2009).Google Scholar
Neumark, David, and Wascher, William. 2000. “Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania: Comment.” American Economic Review 90 (5): 136296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Odgers, Cameron W, and Betts, Julian R. 1997. “Do Unions Reduce Investment? Evidence from Canada.” ILR Review 51 (1): 1836.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oppenheimer, David Benjamin. 2003. “Verdicts Matter: An Empirical Study of California Employment Discrimination and Wrongful Discharge Jury Verdicts Reveals Low Success Rates for Women and Minorities.” U.C. Davis Law Review 37 (2): 51166.Google Scholar
Orbach, Barak Y. 2010. “The Antitrust Consumer Welfare Paradox.” Journal of Competition Law and Economics 7 (1): 13364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Philippon, Thomas, and Reshef, Ariell. 2012. “Wages and Human Capital in the US Finance Industry: 1909-2006.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (4): 1551609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, Thomas, and Saez, Emmanuel. 2003. “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913-1998.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (1): 141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, Thomas, and Saez, Emmanuel. 2012. A Theory of Optimal Capital Taxation. Working Paper Series 17989. National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w17989. www.nber.org/papers/w17989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, Thomas, and Saez, Emmanuel. 2013. “Optimal Labor Income Taxation.” In Handbook of Public Economics, edited by Auerbach, Alan J., Chetty, Raj, Feldstein, Martin, and Saez, Emmanuel, 5: 391474. Amsterdam: Elsevier.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pissarides, Christopher A. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. 2nd ed. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Polinsky, A. Mitchell. 1989. An Introduction to Law and Economics. 2nd ed. Aspen Publishers.Google Scholar
Polinsky, A. Mitchell, and Rogerson, William P.. 1983. “Products Liability, Consumer Misperceptions, and Market Power.” Bell Journal of Economics 14 (2): 58189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polinsky, A. Mitchell, and Shavell, Steven. 2010. “The Uneasy Case for Product Liability.” Harvard Law Review, 123 (6): 143792.Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. 1995. “Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom to Contract.” Journal of Legal Studies 24 (2): 283319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1979. “Utilitarianism, Economics, and Legal Theory.” Journal of Legal Studies 8 (1): 10340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1980. “The Ethical and Political Basis of the Efficiency Norm in Common Law Adjudication.” Hofstra Law Review 8 (3): 487507.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1984. “Some Economics of Labor Law.” University of Chicago Law Review 51 (4): 9881011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1985. “Wealth Maximization Revisited.” Notre Dame Journal of Law, Ethics & Public Policy 2 (1): 85105.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1998. Economic Analysis of Law. 5th ed. New York: Aspen.Google Scholar
Quigley, John M. 2008. “Just Suppose: Housing Subsidies for Low-Income Renters.” In Revisiting Rental Housing: Policies, Programs, and Priorities, edited by Retsinas, Nicolas P and Belsky, Eric S, 30018. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Rabin, Edward H. 1983. “Revolution in Residential Landlord-Tenant Law: Causes and Consequences.” Cornell Law Review 69 (3): 51784.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, John. 1999. A Theory of Justice. Revised edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rebitzer, James B., and Taylor, Lowell J.. 1995. “The Consequences of Minimum Wage Laws: Some New Theoretical Ideas.” Journal of Public Economics 56 (2): 24555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. 1935. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. 2nd ed., rev. and extended. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. 1938. “Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility: A Comment.” Economic Journal 48 (192): 63541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Joan. 1969. The Economics of Imperfect Competition. 2nd ed. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roll, Josh, and McNeil, Nathan. 2022. “Race and Income Disparities in Pedestrian Injuries: Factors Influencing Pedestrian Safety Inequity.” Transportation Research Part D: Transport and Environment 107:103294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rolnick, Arthur, and Davies, Phil. 2006. “The Cost of Kelo.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, June 1, 2006. Accessed January 19, 2023. www.minneapolisfed.org/article/2006/the-cost-of-kelo.Google Scholar
Rothschild, Michael, and Stiglitz, Joseph E.. 1970. “Increasing Risk: I. A Definition.” Journal of Economic Theory 2 (3): 22543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothstein, Jesse. 2010. “Is the EITC as Good as an NIT? Conditional Cash Transfers and Tax Incidence.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 2 (1): 177208.Google Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel. 2000. Optimal Income Transfer Programs: Intensive Versus Extensive Labor Supply Responses. Working Paper Series 7708. National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w7708. www.nber.org/papers/w7708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel. 2002a. “Optimal Income Transfer Programs: Intensive versus Extensive Labor Supply Responses.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (3): 103973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel. 2002b. “The Desirability of Commodity Taxation under Non-Linear Income Taxation and Heterogeneous Tastes.” Journal of Public Economics 83 (2): 21730.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel. 2013. “Optimal Progressive Capital Income Taxes in the Infinite Horizon Model.” Journal of Public Economics 97:6174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salop, Steven. 1977. “The Noisy Monopolist: Imperfect Information, Price Dispersion and Price Discrimination.” Review of Economic Studies 44 (3): 393406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salop, Steven. 1979. “Monopolistic Competition with Outside Goods.” Bell Journal of Economics 10 (1): 14156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salop, Steven. 2010. “Question: What is the Real and Proper Antitrust Welfare Standard? Answer: The True Consumer Welfare Standard.” Loyola Consumer Law Review 22 (3): 33653.Google Scholar
Salop, Steven, and Stiglitz, Joseph E.. 1977. “Bargains and Ripoffs: A Model of Monopolistically Competitive Price Dispersion.” Review of Economic Studies 44 (3): 493510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanchirico, Chris William. 2000. “Taxes versus Legal Rules as Instruments for Equity: A More Equitable View.” Journal of Legal Studies 29 (2): 797820.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanchirico, Chris William. 2001. “Deconstructing the New Efficiency Rationale.” Cornell Law Review 86 (5): 100389.Google Scholar
Sanchirico, Chris William. 2010. “A Critical Look at the Economic Argument for Taxing Only Labor Income.” Tax Law Review 63 (4): 867956.Google Scholar
Sanchirico, Chris William. 2011. “Tax Eclecticism.” Tax Law Review 64 (2): 149227.Google Scholar
Schmalensee, Richard. 1981. “Output andWelfare Implications of Monopolistic Third-Degree Price Discrimination.” American Economic Review 71 (1): 24247.Google Scholar
Schwab, Stewart. 1989. “Coase Defends Coase: Why Lawyers Listen and Economists Do Not.” Michigan Law Review 87 (6): 11712459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segal, Ilya, and Whinston, Michael D.. 2014. “The Efficiency of Bargaining under Divided Entitlements.” University of Chicago Law Review 81 (1): 27389.Google Scholar
Segal, Ilya, and Whinston, Michael D.. 2016. “Property Rights and the Efficiency of Bargaining.” Journal of the European Economic Association 14 (6): 1287328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shavell, Steven. 1979. “On Moral Hazard and Insurance.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 93 (4): 54162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shavell, Steven. 1980. “Strict Liability versus Negligence.” Journal of Legal Studies 9 (1): 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shavell, Steven. 1981. “A Note on Efficiency vs. Distributional Equity in Legal Rulemaking: Should Distributional Equity Matter Given Optimal Income Taxation?American Economic Review 71 (2): 41418.Google Scholar
Shaviro, Daniel. 1997. “The Minimum Wage, the Earned Income Tax Credit, and Optimal Subsidy Policy.” University of Chicago Law Review 64 (2): 40581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silver-Greenberg, Jessica, and Michael Corkery. 2015. “In Arbitration, a ‘Privatization of the Justice System,”' The New York Times (November 1, 2015). www.nytimes.com/2015/11/02 %20/business/dealbook/in-arbitration-a-privatization-of-the-justicesystem.html.Google Scholar
Sims, David P. 2007. “Out of Control: What Can We Learn from the End of Massachusetts Rent Control?Journal of Urban Economics 61 (1): 12951.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smeeding, Timothy. 2012. Income, Wealth, and Debt and the Great Recession. Stanford, CA: Stanford Center on Poverty and Inequality. https://web.stanford.edu/group/ recessiontrends-dev/cgi-bin/web/sites/all/themes/barron/pdf/IncomeWealthDebt_fact_ sheet.pdf.Google Scholar
Smith, Gary R. 2004. “The Future of Tort Reform: Reforming the Remedy, Re-Balancing the Scales.” Emory Law Journal 53 (3): 1219.Google Scholar
Somin, Ilya. 2007. “Controlling the Grasping Hand: Economic Development Takings after KeloSupreme Court Economic Review 15 (1): 183271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Somin, Ilya. 2016. The Grasping Hand: “Kelo v. City of New London” and the Limits of Eminent Domain. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Spence, Michael. 1977. “Consumer Misperceptions, Product Failure and Producer Liability.” Review of Economic Studies 44 (3): 56172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, Muriel Morisey. 1993. “Teaching Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture Co.” Temple Political and Civil Rights Law Review 3:89105.Google Scholar
Stahl, Konrad. 1985. “Microeconomic Analysis of Housing Markets: Towards a Conceptual Framework.” In Microeconomic Models of Housing Markets, edited by Stahl, Konrad, 126. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stark, Kirk J. 2005. “Enslaving the Beachcomber: Some Thoughts on the Liberty Objections to Endowment Taxation.” Canadian Journal of Law & Jurisprudence 18 (1): 4768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sternlight, Jean R. 2001. “Mandatory Binding Arbitration and the Demise of the Seventh Amendment Right to a Jury Trial.” Ohio State Journal of Dispute Resolution 16 (3): 669734.Google Scholar
Sternlight, Jean R. 2011. “Tsunami: AT&T Mobility LLC v. Concepcion Impedes Access to Justice.” Oregon Law Review 90 (3): 70328.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., and Becker, Gary S.. 1977. “De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum.” American Economic Review 67 (2): 7690.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1982. “Self-Selection and Pareto Efficient Taxation.” Journal of Public Economics 17 (2): 21340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1987. “Pareto Efficient and Optimal Taxation and the New New Welfare Economics.” In Handbook of Public Economics, edited by Auerbach, Alan J and Feldstein, Martin, 2:9911042. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2000. Economics of the Public Sector. 3rd ed. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Stole, Lars A., and Zwiebel, Jeffrey. 1996a. “Intra-Firm Bargaining under Non-Binding Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 63 (3): 375410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
1996b. “Organizational Design and Technology Choice under Intrafirm Bargaining.” American Economic Review 86 (1): 195.Google Scholar
Straub, Ludwig, and Werning, Iván. 2020. “Positive Long-Run Capital Taxation: Chamley-Judd Revisited.” American Economic Review 110 (1): 86119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stucke, Maurice E. 2012. “Reconsidering Antitrust's Goals.” Boston College Law Review 53 (2): 551629.Google Scholar
Super, David A. 2011. “The Rise and Fall of the Implied Warranty of Habitability.” California Law Review 99 (2): 389463.Google Scholar
Susin, Scott. 2002. “Rent Vouchers and the Price of Low-Income Housing.” Journal of Public Economics 83 (1): 10952.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suzuki, Keishun. 2020. “Patent Protection, Optimal Licensing, and Innovation with Endogenous Entry.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 24 (8): 20332059.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnerton, Kenneth A. 1996. “Minimum Wages in an Equilibrium Search Model with Diminishing Returns to Labor in Production.” Journal of Labor Economics 14 (2): 34055.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, Mark. 1997. “Letting the Air out of Tort Reform.” ABA Journal 83 (5): 64.Google Scholar
Tramposch, A. 2011. “The Global Impact of the America Invents Act.” WIPO Magazine, no. 6, 6. www.wipo.int/wipo_magazine/en/2011/06/article_0002.html.Google Scholar
Tuomala, Matti. 2016. Optimal Redistributive Taxation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. Chamber Institute for Legal Reform. 2013. International Comparisons of Litigation Costs: Canada, Europe, Japan, and the United States. Washington, DC. https://instituteforlegalreform.com/wp-content/uploads/media/ILR_NERA_Study_International_Liability_Costs-update.pdf.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Labor, Wage and Hour Division. n.d. Federal Minimum Wage Rates under the Fair Labor Standards Act. Accessed February 3, 2022. www.dol.gov/agencies/whd/minimum-wage/history/chart.Google Scholar
Vance, Sarah S. 2005. “A Primer on the Class Action Fairness Act of 2005.” Tulane Law Review 80 (5 & 6): 161744.Google Scholar
Varian, Hal R. 1980. “Redistributive Taxation as Social Insurance.” Journal of Public Economics 14 (1): 4968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, Hal R. 1985. “Price Discrimination and Social Welfare.” American Economic Review 75 (4): 87075.Google Scholar
Varian, Hal R. 1989. “Price Discrimination.” In Handbook of Industrial Organization, edited by Schmalensee, Richard, Armstrong, Mark, Willig, Robert D, and Porter, Robert H, 1:597654. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Waldron, Jeremy. 2003. “Locating Distribution.” Journal of Legal Studies 32 (1): 277302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallerstein, Michael. 1999. “Wage-Setting Institutions and Pay Inequality in Advanced Industrial Societies.” American Journal of Political Science 43 (3): 64980.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisbach, David A. 2003. “Should Legal Rules Be Used to Redistribute Income?University of Chicago Law Review 70 (1): 43953.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisbach, David A. 2015. “Distributionally Weighted Cost-Benefit Analysis: Welfare Economics Meets Organizational Design.” Journal of Legal Analysis 7 (1): 15182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Western, Bruce, and Rosenfeld, Jake. 2011. “Unions, Norms, and the Rise in US Wage Inequality.” American Sociological Review 76 (4): 51337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wickelgren, Abraham L. 2006. “The Inefficiency of Contractually-Based Liability with Rational Consumers.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 22 (1): 16883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1968. “Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs.” American Economic Review 58 (1): 1836.Google Scholar
Wolff, Edward N. 1998. “Recent Trends in the Size Distribution of Household Wealth.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (3): 13150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Joshua D., and Ginsburg, Douglas H.. 2012. “The Goals of Antitrust: Welfare Trumps Choice.” Fordham Law Review 81 (5): 240523.Google Scholar
Wu, Tim. 2019. “Antitrust Returns to American Politics.” The New York Times (March 13,2019). Accessed May 13, 2024. www.nytimes.com/2019/03/13/opinion/antitrust-2020-campaign.html.Google Scholar
Zelenak, Lawrence. 2006. “Taxing Endowment.” Duke Law Journal 55 (6): 1145.Google Scholar

Accessibility standard: Unknown

Accessibility compliance for the PDF of this book is currently unknown and may be updated in the future.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge-org.demo.remotlog.com is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Matthew Dimick, University of Buffalo School of Law
  • Book: Ending Income Inequality
  • Online publication: 09 June 2025
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108906418.015
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Matthew Dimick, University of Buffalo School of Law
  • Book: Ending Income Inequality
  • Online publication: 09 June 2025
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108906418.015
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Matthew Dimick, University of Buffalo School of Law
  • Book: Ending Income Inequality
  • Online publication: 09 June 2025
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108906418.015
Available formats
×